Categories
  Encyclosphere.org ENCYCLOREADER
  supported by EncyclosphereKSF

Pyramid schemes

From Encyclopedia of Mathematics - Reading time: 5 min

Copyright notice
This article Pyramid Schemes was adapted from an original article by Robert T. Smythe, which appeared in StatProb: The Encyclopedia Sponsored by Statistics and Probability Societies. The original article ([http://statprob.com/encyclopedia/PyramidSchemes.html StatProb Source], Local Files: pdf | tex) is copyrighted by the author(s), the article has been donated to Encyclopedia of Mathematics, and its further issues are under Creative Commons Attribution Share-Alike License'. All pages from StatProb are contained in the Category StatProb.


A pyramid scheme is a business model in which payment is made primarily for enrolling other people into the scheme. Some schemes involve a legitimate business venture, but in others no product or services are delivered. A typical pyramid scheme combines a plausible business opportunity (such as a dealership) with a recruiting operation that promises substantial rewards. A recruited individual makes an initial payment, and can earn money by recruiting others who also make a payment; the recruiter receives part of these receipts, and a cut of future payments as the new recruits go on to recruit others. In reality, because of the geometrical progression of (hypothetical) recruits, few participants in a pyramid scheme will be able to recruit enough others to recover their initial investment, let alone make a profit, because the pool of potential recruits is rapidly exhausted.

Although they are illegal in many countries, pyramid schemes have existed for over a century. As recently as November 2008, riots broke out in several towns in Colombia after the collapse of several pyramid schemes, and in 2006 Ireland launched a website to better educate consumers to pyramid fraud after a series of schemes were perpetrated in Cork and Galway.

Perhaps the best-known type of pyramid scheme is a chain letter, which often does not involve even a fictitious product. A chain letter may contain k names; purchasers of the letter invest \$2$x$, with \$$x$ paid to the name at the top of the letter and \$$x$ to the seller of the letter. The purchaser deletes the name at the top of the list, adds his own at the bottom, and sells the letter to new recruits. The promoter's pitch is that if the purchaser, and each subsequent recruit for k-1 stages, sells just two letters, there will be $2^{k-1}$ people selling $2^k$ letters featuring the purchaser's name at the top of the list, so that the participant would net \$$2^kx$ from the venture. Many variants of this basic "get rich quick" scheme have been, and continue to be, promoted.

A structure that can be used to model many pyramid schemes is that of recursive trees. A tree with n vertices labeled $1,2,\ldots, n$ is a "recursive tree if node 1 is distinguished as the root, and for each $j$ with $2 \le j \le n,$ the labels of the vertices in the unique path from the root to node $j$ form an increasing sequence. The special case of random or uniform recursive trees, in which all trees in the set of trees of given order $n$ are equally probable, has been extensively analyzed (cf. [8], for example); however, most pyramid schemes or chain letters in practice have restrictions making their probability models non-uniform. The number of places where the next node may join the tree is then a random variable, unlike the uniform case. This complicates the analysis considerably (and may account for the relative sparsity of mathematical analysis of the properties of pyramid schemes).

Bhattacharya and Gastwirth (1983) analyze a chain letter scheme allowing reentry, in which each purchaser may sell only two letters, unless he purchases a new letter to re-enter the chain. In terms of recursive trees, this means that a node of the tree is saturated once it has two offspring nodes, and no further nodes can attach to it. It is further assumed that at each stage, participants who have not yet sold two letters all have an equal chance to make the next sale, i.e., all unsaturated nodes of the recursive tree have an equal chance of being the ``parent" of the next node to be added. If $L_n$ denotes the number of leaves of the recursive tree (nodes with no offspring) at stage $n$ under this growth rule, $L_n/n$ corresponds to the proportion of ``shutouts" (those receiving no revenue) in this chain letter scheme. The analysis of Bhattacharya and Gastwirth sets up a nonhomogeneous Markov chain model and derives a diffusion approximation for large $n$. They find that $L_n/n$ converges to 0.382 in this model and that the (centered and scaled) number of shutouts has a normally distributed limit. Mahmoud (1994) considers the height $h_n$ of the tree of order $n$ in this same ``random pyramid" scheme and show that it converges with probability 1 to 3.98912; the proof involves embedding the discrete-time growth process of the pyramid in a continuous time birth-and-death process. Mahmoud notes that a similar analysis could be carried out for schemes permitting the sale of m letters, provided that the probabilistic behavior of the total number of shutouts could be derived (as it was in the binary case by Bhattacharya and Gastwirth).

Gastwirth (1977) and Gastwirth and Bhattacharya (1984) analyze another variant of pyramid schemes, known as a quota scheme. This places a limit on the maximum number of participants, so that the scheme corresponds to a recursive tree of some fixed size $n$. This scheme derives from a case in a Connecticut court (Naruk(1975)) in which people bought dealerships in a ``Golden Book of Values", then were paid to recruit other dealers. In this scheme, each participant receives a commission from all of his descendants; thus for the $j^{th}$ participant, the size of the branch of the tree rooted at $j$ determines his profit. If $S_j$ denotes the size of this branch, and $j/n$ converges to a limit $\theta$, Gastwirth and Bhattacharya showed that the distribution of $S_j$ converges to the geometric law

$$P(S_j = i+1) = \theta(1-\theta)^i \ for i=0,1,2,\ldots$$ (It was later shown (cf. [5]) that if $j$ is fixed, the limiting distribution of $S_j/n$ is $Beta(1, j-1).$) Calculations made by Gastwirth and Bhattacharya show that, for example, when $n$ is fixed at $270$, the $135^{th}$ entry has probability only about 0.15 of recruiting two or more new entrants, and probability 0.03 of three or more recruits. Gastwirth (1977) shows that for large $n$, the expected proportion of all participants who are able to recruit at least r persons is $2^{-r}.$

Other variants of pyramid schemes include the ``8-Ball Model" and the ``2-Up System" ([6]). In the 8-Ball model, the participant again recruits two new entrants, but does not receive any payment until two further levels have been successfully recruited. Thus a person at any level in the scheme would theoretically receive $2^3 = 8$ times his ``participation fee", providing incentive to help those in lower levels succeed. In the 2-Up scheme, the income from a participant's first two recruits goes to the individual who recruited the participant; if the participant succeeds in recruiting three or more new entrants, the income received from these goes to the participant, along with the income from the first two sales made by each subsequent recruit. This scheme creates considerable incentive to pursue the potentially lucrative third recruit. For both of these schemes, it is easily calculated that when the pool of prospective recruits is exhausted, the majority of the participants in the scheme end up losing money.




References[edit]

[1] Bhattacharya, P. and J. Gastwirth (1983). A non-homogeneous Markov model of a chain letter scheme, Recent Advances in Statistics: Papers in Honor of Herman Chernoff (Rizvi, M., Rustagi, J. and Siegmund, D., eds.), Academic Press, New York, p. 143-174.
[2] Gastwirth, J. (1977). A probability model of a pyramid scheme, American Statistician 31, 79-82.
[3] Gastwirth, J. and P. Bhattacharya (1984). Two probability models of pyramids or chain letter schemes demonstrating that their promotional claims are unreliable, Operations Research 32, 527-536.
[4] Mahmoud, H. (1994). A strong law for the height of random binary pyramids, Ann. Appl. Probab. 4, 923-932.
[5] Mahmoud, H. and R. T. Smythe (1991). On the distribution of leaves in rooted subtrees of recursive trees, Ann. Prob. 1, 406-418.
[6] http://www.mathmotivation.com/money/pyramid-scheme.html
[7] Naruk, H. (1975). Memorandum of Decision: State of Connecticut versus Bull Investment Group, 32 Conn. Sup. 279.
[8] Smythe, R. T. and H. Mahmoud (1994). A survey of recursive trees, Theor. Probability and Math. Statist. 51, 1-27. Pyramid Schemes is owned by Robert T. Smythe.



How to Cite This Entry: Pyramid schemes (Encyclopedia of Mathematics) | Licensed under CC BY-SA 3.0. Source: https://encyclopediaofmath.org/wiki/Pyramid_schemes
18 views | Status: cached on November 22 2024 00:54:10
↧ Download this article as ZWI file
Encyclosphere.org EncycloReader is supported by the EncyclosphereKSF