Intellectual property

From HandWiki - Reading time: 39 min

Short description: Ownership of creative expressions and processes
Intellectual property laws such as trademark laws forbid the sale of infringing goods like these "McDnoald's" [sic] and "NKIE" [sic] sandals from China .

Intellectual property (IP) is a category of property that includes intangible creations of the human intellect.[1][2] There are many types of intellectual property, and some countries recognize more than others.[3][4][5] The best-known types are patents, copyrights, trademarks, and trade secrets. The modern concept of intellectual property developed in England in the 17th and 18th centuries. The term "intellectual property" began to be used in the 19th century, though it was not until the late 20th century that intellectual property became commonplace in most of the world's legal systems.[6]

Supporters of intellectual property laws often describe their main purpose as encouraging the creation of a wide variety of intellectual goods.[7] To achieve this, the law gives people and businesses property rights to certain information and intellectual goods they create, usually for a limited period of time. Supporters argue that because IP laws allow people to protect their original ideas and prevent unauthorized copying, creators derive greater individual economic benefit from the information and intellectual goods they create, and thus have more economic incentives to create them in the first place.[7] Advocates of IP believe that these economic incentives and legal protections stimulate innovation and contribute to technological progress of certain kinds.[8]

The intangible nature of intellectual property presents difficulties when compared with traditional property like land or goods. Unlike traditional property, intellectual property is "indivisible", since an unlimited number of people can in theory "consume" an intellectual good without its being depleted.[9] Additionally, investments in intellectual goods suffer from appropriation problems: Landowners can surround their land with a robust fence and hire armed guards to protect it, but producers of information or literature can usually do little to stop their first buyer from replicating it and selling it at a lower price. Balancing rights so that they are strong enough to encourage the creation of intellectual goods but not so strong that they prevent the goods' wide use is the primary focus of modern intellectual property law.[10]

History

The Statute of Anne came into force in 1710.

The Venetian Patent Statute of March 19, 1474, established by the Republic of Venice is usually considered to be the earliest codified patent system in the world.[11][12] It states that patents might be granted for "any new and ingenious device, not previously made", provided it was useful. By and large, these principles still remain the basic principles of current patent laws. The Statute of Monopolies (1624) and the British Statute of Anne (1710) are seen as the origins of the current patent law and copyright respectively,[13] firmly establishing the concept of intellectual property.

"Literary property" was the term predominantly used in the British legal debates of the 1760s and 1770s over the extent to which authors and publishers of works also had rights deriving from the common law of property (Millar v Taylor (1769), Hinton v Donaldson (1773), Donaldson v Becket (1774)). The first known use of the term intellectual property dates to this time, when a piece published in the Monthly Review in 1769 used the phrase.[14] The first clear example of modern usage goes back as early as 1808, when it was used as a heading title in a collection of essays.[15]

The German equivalent was used with the founding of the North German Confederation whose constitution granted legislative power over the protection of intellectual property (Schutz des geistigen Eigentums) to the confederation.[16] When the administrative secretariats established by the Paris Convention (1883) and the Berne Convention (1886) merged in 1893, they located in Berne, and also adopted the term intellectual property in their new combined title, the United International Bureaux for the Protection of Intellectual Property.

The organization subsequently relocated to Geneva in 1960 and was succeeded in 1967 with the establishment of the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) by treaty as an agency of the United Nations . According to legal scholar Mark Lemley, it was only at this point that the term really began to be used in the United States (which had not been a party to the Berne Convention),[6] and it did not enter popular usage there until passage of the Bayh–Dole Act in 1980.[17]

The history of patents does not begin with inventions, but rather with royal grants by Queen Elizabeth I (1558–1603) for monopoly privileges. Approximately 200 years after the end of Elizabeth's reign, however, a patent represents a legal right obtained by an inventor providing for exclusive control over the production and sale of his mechanical or scientific invention. demonstrating the evolution of patents from royal prerogative to common-law doctrine.[18]

The term can be found used in an October 1845 Massachusetts Circuit Court ruling in the patent case Davoll et al. v. Brown, in which Justice Charles L. Woodbury wrote that "only in this way can we protect intellectual property, the labors of the mind, productions and interests are as much a man's own ... as the wheat he cultivates, or the flocks he rears."[19] The statement that "discoveries are ... property" goes back earlier. Section 1 of the French law of 1791 stated, "All new discoveries are the property of the author; to assure the inventor the property and temporary enjoyment of his discovery, there shall be delivered to him a patent for five, ten or fifteen years."[20] In Europe, France author A. Nion mentioned propriété intellectuelle in his Droits civils des auteurs, artistes et inventeurs, published in 1846.

Until recently, the purpose of intellectual property law was to give as little protection as possible in order to encourage innovation. Historically, therefore, legal protection was granted only when necessary to encourage invention, and it was limited in time and scope.[21] This is mainly as a result of knowledge being traditionally viewed as a public good, in order to allow its extensive dissemination and improvement.[22]

The concept's origin can potentially be traced back further. Jewish law includes several considerations whose effects are similar to those of modern intellectual property laws, though the notion of intellectual creations as property does not seem to exist—notably the principle of Hasagat Ge'vul (unfair encroachment) was used to justify limited-term publisher (but not author) copyright in the 16th century.[23] In 500 BCE, the government of the Greek state of Sybaris offered one year's patent "to all who should discover any new refinement in luxury".[24]

According to Jean-Frédéric Morin, "the global intellectual property regime is currently in the midst of a paradigm shift".[25] Indeed, up until the early 2000s the global IP regime used to be dominated by high standards of protection characteristic of IP laws from Europe or the United States, with a vision that uniform application of these standards over every country and to several fields with little consideration over social, cultural or environmental values or of the national level of economic development. Morin argues that "the emerging discourse of the global IP regime advocates for greater policy flexibility and greater access to knowledge, especially for developing countries." Indeed, with the Development Agenda adopted by WIPO in 2007, a set of 45 recommendations to adjust WIPO's activities to the specific needs of developing countries and aim to reduce distortions especially on issues such as patients' access to medicines, Internet users' access to information, farmers' access to seeds, programmers' access to source codes or students' access to scientific articles.[26] However, this paradigm shift has not yet manifested itself in concrete legal reforms at the international level.[27]

Similarly, it is based on these background that the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreement requires members of the WTO to set minimum standards of legal protection, but its objective to have a "one-fits-all" protection law on Intellectual Property has been viewed with controversies regarding differences in the development level of countries.[28] Despite the controversy, the agreement has extensively incorporated intellectual property rights into the global trading system for the first time in 1995, and has prevailed as the most comprehensive agreement reached by the world.[29]

Rights

Intellectual property rights include patents, copyright, industrial design rights, trademarks, plant variety rights, trade dress, geographical indications,[30] and in some jurisdictions trade secrets. There are also more specialized or derived varieties of sui generis exclusive rights, such as circuit design rights (called mask work rights in the US), supplementary protection certificates for pharmaceutical products (after expiry of a patent protecting them), and database rights (in European law). The term "industrial property" is sometimes used to refer to a large subset of intellectual property rights including patents, trademarks, industrial designs, utility models, service marks, trade names, and geographical indications.[31]

Patents

Main page: Social:Patent

A patent is a form of right granted by the government to an inventor or their successor-in-title, giving the owner the right to exclude others from making, using, selling, offering to sell, and importing an invention for a limited period of time, in exchange for the public disclosure of the invention. An invention is a solution to a specific technological problem, which may be a product or a process, and generally has to fulfill three main requirements: it has to be new, not obvious and there needs to be an industrial applicability.[32]:17 To enrich the body of knowledge and to stimulate innovation, it is an obligation for patent owners to disclose valuable information about their inventions to the public.[33]

Copyright

Main page: Copyright

A copyright gives the creator of an original work exclusive rights to it, usually for a limited time. Copyright may apply to a wide range of creative, intellectual, or artistic forms, or "works".[34][35] Copyright does not cover ideas and information themselves, only the form or manner in which they are expressed.[36]

Industrial design rights

Main page: Social:Industrial design right

An industrial design right (sometimes called "design right" or design patent) protects the visual design of objects that are not purely utilitarian. An industrial design consists of the creation of a shape, configuration or composition of pattern or color, or combination of pattern and color in three-dimensional form containing aesthetic value. An industrial design can be a two- or three-dimensional pattern used to produce a product, industrial commodity or handicraft. Generally speaking, it is what makes a product look appealing, and as such, it increases the commercial value of goods.[33]

Plant varieties

Main page: Biology:Plant breeders' rights

Plant breeders' rights or plant variety rights are the rights to commercially use a new variety of a plant. The variety must, amongst others, be novel and distinct and for registration the evaluation of propagating material of the variety is considered.

Trademarks

Main page: Social:Trademark

A trademark is a recognizable sign, design or expression that distinguishes a particular trader's products or services from similar products or services of other traders.[37][38][39]

Trade dress

Main page: Social:Trade dress

Trade dress is a legal term of art that generally refers to characteristics of the visual and aesthetic appearance of a product or its packaging (or even the design of a building) that signify the source of the product to consumers.[40]

Trade secrets

Main page: Social:Trade secret

A trade secret is a formula, practice, process, design, instrument, pattern, or compilation of information which is not generally known or reasonably ascertainable, by which a business can obtain an economic advantage over competitors and customers. There is no formal government protection granted; each business must take measures to guard its own trade secrets (e.g., Formula of its soft drinks is a trade secret for Coca-Cola.)

Motivation and justification

The main purpose of intellectual property law is to encourage the creation of a wide variety of intellectual goods for consumers.[7] To achieve this, the law gives people and businesses property rights to the information and intellectual goods they create, usually for a limited period of time. Because they can then profit from them, this gives economic incentive for their creation.[7] The intangible nature of intellectual property presents difficulties when compared with traditional property like land or goods. Unlike traditional property, intellectual property is indivisible – an unlimited number of people can "consume" an intellectual good without it being depleted. Additionally, investments in intellectual goods suffer from problems of appropriation – while a landowner can surround their land with a robust fence and hire armed guards to protect it, a producer of information or an intellectual good can usually do very little to stop their first buyer from replicating it and selling it at a lower price. Balancing rights so that they are strong enough to encourage the creation of information and intellectual goods but not so strong that they prevent their wide use is the primary focus of modern intellectual property law.[10]

By exchanging limited exclusive rights for disclosure of inventions and creative works, society and the patentee/copyright owner mutually benefit, and an incentive is created for inventors and authors to create and disclose their work. Some commentators have noted that the objective of intellectual property legislators and those who support its implementation appears to be "absolute protection". "If some intellectual property is desirable because it encourages innovation, they reason, more is better. The thinking is that creators will not have sufficient incentive to invent unless they are legally entitled to capture the full social value of their inventions".[21] This absolute protection or full value view treats intellectual property as another type of "real" property, typically adopting its law and rhetoric. Other recent developments in intellectual property law, such as the America Invents Act, stress international harmonization. Recently there has also been much debate over the desirability of using intellectual property rights to protect cultural heritage, including intangible ones, as well as over risks of commodification derived from this possibility.[41] The issue still remains open in legal scholarship.

Financial incentive

These exclusive rights allow intellectual property owners to benefit from the property they have created, providing a financial incentive for the creation of an investment in intellectual property, and, in case of patents, pay associated research and development costs.[42] In the United States Article I Section 8 Clause 8 of the Constitution, commonly called the Patent and Copyright Clause, reads; "The Congress shall have power 'To promote the progress of science and useful arts, by securing for limited times to authors and inventors the exclusive right to their respective writings and discoveries.'"[43] "Some commentators, such as David Levine and Michele Boldrin, dispute this justification.[44]

In 2013 the United States Patent & Trademark Office approximated that the worth of intellectual property to the U.S. economy is more than US $5 trillion and creates employment for an estimated 18 million American people. The value of intellectual property is considered similarly high in other developed nations, such as those in the European Union.[45] In the UK, IP has become a recognised asset class for use in pension-led funding and other types of business finance. However, in 2013, the UK Intellectual Property Office stated: "There are millions of intangible business assets whose value is either not being leveraged at all, or only being leveraged inadvertently".[46]

Economic growth

The WIPO treaty and several related international agreements underline that the protection of intellectual property rights is essential to maintaining economic growth. The WIPO Intellectual Property Handbook gives two reasons for intellectual property laws:

One is to give statutory expression to the moral and economic rights of creators in their creations and the rights of the public in access to those creations. The second is to promote, as a deliberate act of Government policy, creativity and the dissemination and application of its results and to encourage fair trading which would contribute to economic and social development.[47]

The Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement (ACTA) states that "effective enforcement of intellectual property rights is critical to sustaining economic growth across all industries and globally".[48]

Economists estimate that two-thirds of the value of large businesses in the United States can be traced to intangible assets.[49] "IP-intensive industries" are estimated to generate 72% more value added (price minus material cost) per employee than "non-IP-intensive industries".[50][dubious ]

A joint research project of the WIPO and the United Nations University measuring the impact of IP systems on six Asian countries found "a positive correlation between the strengthening of the IP system and subsequent economic growth."[51]

Morality

According to Article 27 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, "everyone has the right to the protection of the moral and material interests resulting from any scientific, literary or artistic production of which he is the author".[52] Although the relationship between intellectual property and human rights is complex,[53] there are moral arguments for intellectual property.

The arguments that justify intellectual property fall into three major categories. Personality theorists believe intellectual property is an extension of an individual. Utilitarians believe that intellectual property stimulates social progress and pushes people to further innovation. Lockeans argue that intellectual property is justified based on deservedness and hard work.[54]

Various moral justifications for private property can be used to argue in favor of the morality of intellectual property, such as:

  1. Natural Rights/Justice Argument: this argument is based on Locke's idea that a person has a natural right over the labour and products which are produced by their body. Appropriating these products is viewed as unjust. Although Locke had never explicitly stated that natural right applied to products of the mind,[55] it is possible to apply his argument to intellectual property rights, in which it would be unjust for people to misuse another's ideas.[56] Locke's argument for intellectual property is based upon the idea that laborers have the right to control that which they create. They argue that we own our bodies which are the laborers, this right of ownership extends to what we create. Thus, intellectual property ensures this right when it comes to production.
  2. Utilitarian-Pragmatic Argument: according to this rationale, a society that protects private property is more effective and prosperous than societies that do not. Innovation and invention in 19th century America has been attributed to the development of the patent system.[57] By providing innovators with "durable and tangible return on their investment of time, labor, and other resources", intellectual property rights seek to maximize social utility.[58] The presumption is that they promote public welfare by encouraging the "creation, production, and distribution of intellectual works".[58] Utilitarians argue that without intellectual property there would be a lack of incentive to produce new ideas. Systems of protection such as Intellectual property optimize social utility.
  3. "Personality" Argument: this argument is based on a quote from Hegel: "Every man has the right to turn his will upon a thing or make the thing an object of his will, that is to say, to set aside the mere thing and recreate it as his own".[59] European intellectual property law is shaped by this notion that ideas are an "extension of oneself and of one's personality".[60] Personality theorists argue that by being a creator of something one is inherently at risk and vulnerable for having their ideas and designs stolen and/or altered. Intellectual property protects these moral claims that have to do with personality.

Lysander Spooner (1855) argues "that a man has a natural and absolute right—and if a natural and absolute, then necessarily a perpetual, right—of property, in the ideas, of which he is the discoverer or creator; that his right of property, in ideas, is intrinsically the same as, and stands on identically the same grounds with, his right of property in material things; that no distinction, of principle, exists between the two cases".[61]

Writer Ayn Rand argued in her book Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal that the protection of intellectual property is essentially a moral issue. The belief is that the human mind itself is the source of wealth and survival and that all property at its base is intellectual property. To violate intellectual property is therefore no different morally than violating other property rights which compromises the very processes of survival and therefore constitutes an immoral act.[62]

Infringement, misappropriation, and enforcement

Main page: Social:Intellectual property infringement

Violation of intellectual property rights, called "infringement" with respect to patents, copyright, and trademarks, and "misappropriation" with respect to trade secrets, may be a breach of civil law or criminal law, depending on the type of intellectual property involved, jurisdiction, and the nature of the action.

As of 2011, trade in counterfeit copyrighted and trademarked works was a $600 billion industry worldwide and accounted for 5–7% of global trade.[63] During the 2022 Russian invasion of Ukraine, IP has been a consideration in punishment of the aggressor through trade sanctions,[64] has been proposed as a method to prevent future wars of aggression involving nuclear weapons,[65] and has caused concern about stifling innovation by keeping patent information secret.[66]

Patent infringement

Main page: Social:Patent infringement

Patent infringement typically is caused by using or selling a patented invention without permission from the patent holder, i.e. from the patent owner. The scope of the patented invention or the extent of protection[67] is defined in the claims of the granted patent. There is safe harbor in many jurisdictions to use a patented invention for research. This safe harbor does not exist in the US unless the research is done for purely philosophical purposes, or to gather data to prepare an application for regulatory approval of a drug.[68] In general, patent infringement cases are handled under civil law (e.g., in the United States) but several jurisdictions incorporate infringement in criminal law also (for example, Argentina, China, France, Japan, Russia, South Korea).[69]

Copyright infringement

Main page: Copyright infringement

Copyright infringement is reproducing, distributing, displaying or performing a work, or to make derivative works, without permission from the copyright holder, which is typically a publisher or other business representing or assigned by the work's creator. It is often called "piracy".[70] In the United States, while copyright is created the instant a work is fixed, generally the copyright holder can only get money damages if the owner registers the copyright.[71] Enforcement of copyright is generally the responsibility of the copyright holder.[72] The ACTA trade agreement, signed in May 2011 by the United States, Japan, Switzerland, and the EU, and which has not entered into force, requires that its parties add criminal penalties, including incarceration and fines, for copyright and trademark infringement, and obligated the parties to actively police for infringement.[63][73] There are limitations and exceptions to copyright, allowing limited use of copyrighted works, which does not constitute infringement. Examples of such doctrines are the fair use and fair dealing doctrine.

Trademark infringement

Trademark infringement occurs when one party uses a trademark that is identical or confusingly similar to a trademark owned by another party, in relation to products or services which are identical or similar to the products or services of the other party. In many countries, a trademark receives protection without registration, but registering a trademark provides legal advantages for enforcement. Infringement can be addressed by civil litigation and, in several jurisdictions, under criminal law.[63][73]

Trade secret misappropriation

Trade secret misappropriation is different from violations of other intellectual property laws, since by definition trade secrets are secret, while patents and registered copyrights and trademarks are publicly available. In the United States, trade secrets are protected under state law, and states have nearly universally adopted the Uniform Trade Secrets Act. The United States also has federal law in the form of the Economic Espionage Act of 1996 (18 U.S.C. §§ 18311839), which makes the theft or misappropriation of a trade secret a federal crime. This law contains two provisions criminalizing two sorts of activity. The first, 18 U.S.C. § 1831(a), criminalizes the theft of trade secrets to benefit foreign powers. The second, 18 U.S.C. § 1832, criminalizes their theft for commercial or economic purposes. (The statutory penalties are different for the two offenses.) In Commonwealth common law jurisdictions, confidentiality and trade secrets are regarded as an equitable right rather than a property right but penalties for theft are roughly the same as in the United States.[citation needed]

International framework

The international governance of IP involves multiple overlapping institutions and forums.[74](p25) There is no overall rule-making body.[74](p25)

One of the most important aspects of global IP governance is the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS).[74](p7) The TRIPS Agreement sets minimum international standards for IP which every member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) must comply with.[74](p7) A member's non-compliance with the TRIPS Agreement may be grounds for suit under the WTO's Dispute Settlement Mechanism.[74](p7)

Bilateral and multi-lateral agreements often establish IP requirements above the requirements of the TRIPS Agreement.[74](p7)

Criticisms

Demonstration in Sweden in support of file sharing, 2006
"Copying is not theft!" badge with a character resembling Mickey Mouse in reference to the "in popular culture" rationale behind the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998

The term "intellectual property"

Criticism of the term intellectual property ranges from discussing its vagueness and abstract overreach to direct contention to the semantic validity of using words like property and rights in fashions that contradict practice and law. Many detractors think this term specially serves the doctrinal agenda of parties opposing reform in the public interest or otherwise abusing related legislations, and that it disallows intelligent discussion about specific and often unrelated aspects of copyright, patents, trademarks, etc.[75]

Free Software Foundation founder Richard Stallman argues that, although the term intellectual property is in wide use, it should be rejected altogether, because it "systematically distorts and confuses these issues, and its use was and is promoted by those who gain from this confusion". He claims that the term "operates as a catch-all to lump together disparate laws [which] originated separately, evolved differently, cover different activities, have different rules, and raise different public policy issues" and that it creates a "bias" by confusing these monopolies with ownership of limited physical things, likening them to "property rights".[76] Stallman advocates referring to copyrights, patents and trademarks in the singular and warns against abstracting disparate laws into a collective term. He argues that, "to avoid spreading unnecessary bias and confusion, it is best to adopt a firm policy not to speak or even think in terms of 'intellectual property'."[77]

Similarly, economists Boldrin and Levine prefer to use the term "intellectual monopoly" as a more appropriate and clear definition of the concept, which, they argue, is very dissimilar from property rights.[78] They further argued that "stronger patents do little or nothing to encourage innovation", mainly explained by its tendency to create market monopolies, thereby restricting further innovations and technology transfer.[79]

On the assumption that intellectual property rights are actual rights, Stallman says that this claim does not live to the historical intentions behind these laws, which in the case of copyright served as a censorship system, and later on, a regulatory model for the printing press that may have benefited authors incidentally, but never interfered with the freedom of average readers.[80] Still referring to copyright, he cites legal literature such as the United States Constitution and case law to demonstrate that the law is meant to be an optional and experimental bargain to temporarily trade property rights and free speech for public, not private, benefits in the form of increased artistic production and knowledge. He mentions that "if copyright were a natural right nothing could justify terminating this right after a certain period of time".[81]

Law professor, writer and political activist Lawrence Lessig, along with many other copyleft and free software activists, has criticized the implied analogy with physical property (like land or an automobile). They argue such an analogy fails because physical property is generally rivalrous while intellectual works are non-rivalrous (that is, if one makes a copy of a work, the enjoyment of the copy does not prevent enjoyment of the original).[82][83] Other arguments along these lines claim that unlike the situation with tangible property, there is no natural scarcity of a particular idea or information: once it exists at all, it can be re-used and duplicated indefinitely without such re-use diminishing the original. Stephan Kinsella has objected to intellectual property on the grounds that the word "property" implies scarcity, which may not be applicable to ideas.[84]

Entrepreneur and politician Rickard Falkvinge and hacker Alexandre Oliva have independently compared George Orwell's fictional dialect Newspeak to the terminology used by intellectual property supporters as a linguistic weapon to shape public opinion regarding copyright debate and DRM.[85][86]

Alternative terms

In civil law jurisdictions, intellectual property has often been referred to as intellectual rights, traditionally a somewhat broader concept that has included moral rights and other personal protections that cannot be bought or sold. Use of the term intellectual rights has declined since the early 1980s, as use of the term intellectual property has increased.

Alternative terms monopolies on information and intellectual monopoly have emerged among those who argue against the "property" or "intellect" or "rights" assumptions, notably Richard Stallman. The backronyms intellectual protectionism and intellectual poverty,[87] whose initials are also IP, have also found supporters, especially among those who have used the backronym digital restrictions management.[88][89]

The argument that an intellectual property right should (in the interests of better balancing of relevant private and public interests) be termed an intellectual monopoly privilege (IMP) has been advanced by several academics including Birgitte Andersen[90] and Thomas Alured Faunce.[91]

Objections to overly broad intellectual property laws

The free culture movement champions the production of content that bears little or no restrictions.

Some critics of intellectual property, such as those in the free culture movement, point at intellectual monopolies as harming health (in the case of pharmaceutical patents), preventing progress, and benefiting concentrated interests to the detriment of the masses,[92][93][94][95] and argue that ever-expansive monopolies in the form of copyright extensions, software patents, and business method patents harm the public interest. More recently scientists and engineers are expressing concern that patent thickets are undermining technological development even in high-tech fields like nanotechnology.[96][97]

Petra Moser has asserted that historical analysis suggests that intellectual property laws may harm innovation:

Overall, the weight of the existing historical evidence suggests that patent policies, which grant strong intellectual property rights to early generations of inventors, may discourage innovation. On the contrary, policies that encourage the diffusion of ideas and modify patent laws to facilitate entry and encourage competition may be an effective mechanism to encourage innovation.[98]

In support of that argument, Jörg Baten, Nicola Bianchi and Petra Moser[99] find historical evidence that especially compulsory licensing – which allows governments to license patents without the consent of patent-owners – encouraged invention in Germany in the early 20th century by increasing the threat of competition in fields with low pre-existing levels of competition.

Peter Drahos notes, "Property rights confer authority over resources. When authority is granted to the few over resources on which the many depend, the few gain power over the goals of the many. This has consequences for both political and economic freedom within a society."[100]:13

The World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) recognizes that conflicts may exist between respecting and implementing current intellectual property systems and other human rights.[101] In 2001 the UN Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights issued a document called "Human rights and intellectual property" that argued that intellectual property tends to be governed by economic goals when it should be viewed primarily as a social product; in order to serve human well-being, intellectual property systems must respect and conform to human rights laws. According to the Committee, when systems fail to do so, they risk infringing upon the human right to food and health, and to cultural participation and scientific benefits.[102][103] In 2004 the General Assembly of WIPO adopted The Geneva Declaration on the Future of the World Intellectual Property Organization which argues that WIPO should "focus more on the needs of developing countries, and to view IP as one of many tools for development—not as an end in itself".[104]

Ethical problems are most pertinent when socially valuable goods like life-saving medicines are given IP protection. While the application of IP rights can allow companies to charge higher than the marginal cost of production in order to recoup the costs of research and development, the price may exclude from the market anyone who cannot afford the cost of the product, in this case a life-saving drug.[105] "An IPR driven regime is therefore not a regime that is conductive to the investment of R&D of products that are socially valuable to predominately poor populations".[105]:1108–9

Libertarians have differing views on intellectual property.[106] Stephan Kinsella, an anarcho-capitalist on the right-wing of libertarianism,[107] argues against intellectual property because allowing property rights in ideas and information creates artificial scarcity and infringes on the right to own tangible property. Kinsella uses the following scenario to argue this point:

[I]magine the time when men lived in caves. One bright guy—let's call him Galt-Magnon—decides to build a log cabin on an open field, near his crops. To be sure, this is a good idea, and others notice it. They naturally imitate Galt-Magnon, and they start building their own cabins. But the first man to invent a house, according to IP advocates, would have a right to prevent others from building houses on their own land, with their own logs, or to charge them a fee if they do build houses. It is plain that the innovator in these examples becomes a partial owner of the tangible property (e.g., land and logs) of others, due not to first occupation and use of that property (for it is already owned), but due to his coming up with an idea. Clearly, this rule flies in the face of the first-user homesteading rule, arbitrarily and groundlessly overriding the very homesteading rule that is at the foundation of all property rights.[108]

Thomas Jefferson once said in a letter to Isaac McPherson on 13 August 1813:

If nature has made any one thing less susceptible than all others of exclusive property, it is the action of the thinking power called an idea, which an individual may exclusively possess as long as he keeps it to himself; but the moment it is divulged, it forces itself into the possession of every one, and the receiver cannot dispossess himself of it. Its peculiar character, too, is that no one possesses the less, because every other possesses the whole of it. He who receives an idea from me, receives instruction himself without lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me.[109]

In 2005 the Royal Society of Arts launched the Adelphi Charter, aimed at creating an international policy statement to frame how governments should make balanced intellectual property law.[110]

Another aspect of current U.S. Intellectual Property legislation is its focus on individual and joint works; thus, copyright protection can only be obtained in 'original' works of authorship. Critics like Philip Bennet argue that this does not provide adequate protection against cultural appropriation of indigenous knowledge, for which a collective IP regime is needed.[111]

Intellectual property law has been criticized as not recognizing new forms of art such as the remix culture, whose participants often commit what technically constitutes violations of such laws, creation works such as anime music videos and others, or are otherwise subject to unnecessary burdens and limitations which prevent them from fully expressing themselves.[112]:70[113][114][115]

Objections to the expansion in nature and scope of intellectual property laws

Expansion of U.S. copyright law (assuming authors create their works by age 35 and live for seventy years)

Other criticism of intellectual property law concerns the expansion of intellectual property, both in duration and in scope.

As scientific knowledge has expanded and allowed new industries to arise in fields such as biotechnology and nanotechnology, originators of technology have sought IP protection for the new technologies. Patents have been granted for living organisms,[116] and in the United States, certain living organisms have been patentable for over a century.[117]

The increase in terms of protection is particularly seen in relation to copyright, which has recently been the subject of serial extensions in the United States and in Europe.[82][118][119][120][121] With no need for registration or copyright notices, this is thought to have led to an increase in orphan works (copyrighted works for which the copyright owner cannot be contacted), a problem that has been noticed and addressed by governmental bodies around the world.[122]

Also with respect to copyright, the American film industry helped to change the social construct of intellectual property via its trade organization, the Motion Picture Association of America (MPAA). In amicus briefs in important cases, in lobbying before Congress, and in its statements to the public, the MPAA has advocated strong protection of intellectual property rights. In framing its presentations, the association has claimed that people are entitled to the property that is produced by their labor. Additionally Congress's awareness of the position of the United States as the world's largest producer of films has made it convenient to expand the conception of intellectual property.[123] These doctrinal reforms have further strengthened the industry, lending the MPAA even more power and authority.[124]

The growth of the Internet, and particularly distributed search engines like Kazaa and Gnutella, have represented a challenge for copyright policy. The Recording Industry Association of America, in particular, has been on the front lines of the fight against copyright infringement, which the industry calls "piracy". The industry has had victories against some services, including a highly publicized case against the file-sharing company Napster, and some people have been prosecuted for sharing files in violation of copyright. The electronic age has seen an increase in the attempt to use software-based digital rights management tools to restrict the copying and use of digitally based works. Laws such as the Digital Millennium Copyright Act have been enacted that use criminal law to prevent any circumvention of software used to enforce digital rights management systems. Equivalent provisions, to prevent circumvention of copyright protection have existed in EU for some time, and are being expanded in, for example, Article 6 and 7 the Copyright Directive. Other examples are Article 7 of the Software Directive of 1991 (91/250/EEC), and the Conditional Access Directive of 1998 (98/84/EEC). This can hinder legal uses, affecting public domain works, limitations and exceptions to copyright, or uses allowed by the copyright holder. Some copyleft licenses, like the GNU GPL 3, are designed to counter this.[125] Laws may permit circumvention under specific conditions, such as when it is necessary to achieve interoperability with the circumventor's program, or for accessibility reasons; however, distribution of circumvention tools or instructions may be illegal.

In the context of trademarks, this expansion has been driven by international efforts to harmonise the definition of "trademark", as exemplified by the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights ratified in 1994, which formalized regulations for IP rights that had been handled by common law, or not at all, in member states. Pursuant to TRIPs, any sign which is "capable of distinguishing" the products or services of one business from the products or services of another business is capable of constituting a trademark.[126]

Use in corporate tax avoidance

Make no mistake: the headline [tax] rate is not what triggers tax evasion and aggressive tax planning. That comes from schemes that facilitate profit shifting.

Pierre Moscovici
European Commissioner for Tax
Financial Times, 11 March 2018[127]

Intellectual property has become a core tool in corporate tax planning and tax avoidance.[128][129][130] IP is a key component of the leading multinational tax avoidance base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) tools,[131][132] which the OECD estimates costs $100–240 billion in lost annual tax revenues.[133]

In 2017–2018, both the U.S. and the EU Commission simultaneously decided to depart from the OECD BEPS Project timetable, which was set up in 2013 to combat IP BEPS tax tools like the above,[133] and launch their own anti-IP BEPS tax regimes:

  • U.S. Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017, which has several anti-IP BEPS abuse tax regimes, including GILTI tax and the BEAT tax regimes.[134][135][136]
  • EU Commission 2018 Digital Services Tax, which is less advanced than the U.S. TCJA, but does seek to override IP BEPS tools via a quasi-VAT.[137][138][139]

The departure of the U.S. and EU Commission from the OECD BEPS Project process, is attributed to frustrations with the rise in IP as a key BEPS tax tool, creating intangible assets, which are then turned into royalty payment BEPS schemes (double Irish), and/or capital allowance BEPS schemes (capital allowances for intangibles). In contrast, the OECD has spent years developing and advocating intellectual property as a legal and a GAAP accounting concept.[140]

Gender gap in intellectual property

Women have historically been underrepresented in the creation and ownership of intellectual property covered by intellectual property rights. According to the World Intellectual Property Organization, women composed only 16.5% of patent holders even as recently as 2020.[141] This disparity is the result of several factors including systemic bias, sexism and discrimination within the intellectual property space, underrepresentation within STEM, and barriers to access of necessary finance and knowledge in order to obtain intellectual property rights, among other reasons.[142]

Global IP ratchet and developing countries

The global increase in intellectual property protection is sometimes referred to as a global IP ratchet in which a spiral of bilateral and multilateral agreements result in growing obligations where new agreements never recede from existing standards and very often further heighten them.[74](p7)

The global IP ratchet has limited the freedom of developing countries to set their own IP standards.[74](p7) Developing countries' lack of bargaining power relative to the developed countries driving the global IP ratchet means that developing countries' ability to regulate intellectual property to advance domestic interests is eroding.[74](pp6–7)

See also

References

Citations

  1. World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) (2016). Understanding Industrial Property. World Intellectual Property Organization. doi:10.34667/tind.36288. ISBN 9789280525939. https://www.wipo.int/publications/en/details.jsp?id=4080. Retrieved 6 December 2018. 
  2. "Intellectual, industrial and commercial property | Fact Sheets on the European Union". European Parliament. http://www.europarl.europa.eu/factsheets/en/sheet/36/intellectual-industrial-and-commercial-property. 
  3. "What are intellectual property rights?". https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/intel1_e.htm. 
  4. World Intellectual Property Organization (2021). What is Intellectual Property?. WIPO publication. World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO). doi:10.34667/tind.43765. ISBN 9789280532210. https://www.wipo.int/publications/en/details.jsp?id=4528. Retrieved 23 October 2020. 
  5. "Understanding Industrial Property". World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO). https://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/wipo_pub_895_2016.pdf. 
  6. 6.0 6.1 "property as a common descriptor of the field probably traces to the foundation of the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) by the United Nations." in Mark A. Lemley, Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding , Texas Law Review, 2005, Vol. 83:1031, page 1033, footnote 4.
  7. 7.0 7.1 7.2 7.3 Goldstein & Reese (2008), p. 17.
  8. "The Role of Intellectual Property Rights in Technology Transfer and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence". https://www.unido.org/sites/default/files/2009-04/Role_of_intellectual_property_rights_in_technology_transfer_and_economic_growth_0.pdf. 
  9. Moberly, Michael D. (2014). Safeguarding Intangible Assets. Butterworth-Heinemann. pp. 33–35. ISBN 978-0-12-800516-3. https://www.sciencedirect.com/book/9780128005163/safeguarding-intangible-assets. 
  10. 10.0 10.1 Goldstein & Reese (2008), pp. 18–19.
  11. Ladas, Stephen Pericles (1975). Patents, trademarks, and related rights: national and international protection. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-65775-5. 
  12. Teich, Mikuláš, ed (1996). The industrial revolution in national context: Europe and the USA (1. publ ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. ISBN 978-0-521-40940-7. 
  13. Brad, Sherman; Lionel Bently (1999). The making of modern intellectual property law: the British experience, 1760–1911. Cambridge University Press. p. 207. ISBN 978-0-521-56363-5. https://books.google.com/books?id=u2aMRA-eF1gC&q=statute+of+anne+copyright. 
  14. intellectual property (3rd ed.), Oxford University Press, September 2005, http://oed.com/search?searchType=dictionary&q=intellectual+property  (Subscription or UK public library membership required.) (Citing Monthly Review, vol. 41. p. 290 (1769): "What a niggard this Doctor is of his own, and how profuse he is of other people's intellectual property.")
  15. intellectual property (3rd ed.), Oxford University Press, September 2005, http://oed.com/search?searchType=dictionary&q=intellectual+property  (Subscription or UK public library membership required.) (Citing Medical Repository Of Original Essays And Intelligence, vol. 11. p. 303 (1808): "New-England Association in favour of Inventors and Discoverers, and particularly for the Protection of intellectual Property.")
  16. 'Article 4 No. 6 of the Constitution of 1867 (German)' Hastings Law Journal, Vol. 52, p. 1255, 2001
  17. Mark A. Lemley, "Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding" (Abstract); see Table 1: 4–5.
  18. Mossoff, A. 'Rethinking the Development of Patents: An Intellectual History, 1550–1800,' Hastings Law Journal, Vol. 52, p. 1255, 2001
  19. 1 Woodb. & M. 53, 3 West. L.J. 151, 7 F.Cas. 197, No. 3662, 2 Robb.Pat.Cas. 303, Merw.Pat.Inv. 414
  20. "Patent Archives – Ladas & Parry LLP". Ladas.com. http://www.ladas.com/Patents/USPatentHistory.html. 
  21. 21.0 21.1 Mark A. Lemley. "Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding". Heinonline.org. http://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/tlr83&div=30&g_sent=1&collection=journals. 
  22. "The liquidity of innovation". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. https://www.economist.com/special-report/2005/10/22/the-liquidity-of-innovation. 
  23. "Jewish Law – Articles ("Jewish Law and Copyright")". Jlaw.com. http://www.jlaw.com/Articles/copyright1.html. 
  24. Charles Anthon, A Classical Dictionary: Containing an Account of the Principal Proper Names Mentioned in Ancient Authors, and Intended to Elucidate All the Important Points Connected with the Geography, History, Biography, Mythology, and Fine Arts of the Greek and Romans. Together with an Account of Coins, Weights, and Measures, with Tabular Values of the Same 1273 (Harper & Brothers 1841). See also "The first patent law was enacted in Sybaris, a city in the South of Italy, before the Roman domination; The law was mentioned by Atheneus, an ancient writer..." in Takenaka, Toshiko (2013). Intellectual Property in Common Law and Civil Law. Edward Elgar Publishing, p. 419. (chapter by Mario Franzosi).
  25. Morin, Jean-Frédéric. "Paradigm shift in the global IP regime: The agency of academics, Review of International Political Economy, vol 21-2, 2014, p. 275". http://www.chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/sites/chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/files/publications/morin_2014_paradigm_shift_agency_of_academics.pdf. 
  26. Morin, Jean-Frédéric. "Paradigm shift in the global IP regime: The agency of academics, Review of International Political Economy, vol 21-2, 2014, p. 275". http://www.chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/sites/chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/files/publications/morin_2014_paradigm_shift_agency_of_academics.pdf. 
  27. Morin, Jean-Frédéric. "Paradigm shift in the global IP regime: The agency of academics, Review of International Political Economy, vol 21-2, 2014, p. 275". http://www.chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/sites/chaire-epi.ulaval.ca/files/publications/morin_2014_paradigm_shift_agency_of_academics.pdf. 
  28. Roisah, Kholis (26 December 2017). "Understanding Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights Agreement: From Hard and Soft Law Perspective". Hasanuddin Law Review 3 (3): 277–289. doi:10.20956/halrev.v3i3.1153. ISSN 2442-9899. 
  29. "WTO | intellectual property (TRIPS) - Responding to least developed countries' special needs in intellectual property". https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/ldc_e.htm. 
  30. Article 1(2) of the Paris Convention: "The protection of industrial property has as its object patents, utility models, industrial designs, trademarks, service marks, trade names, indications of source or appellations of origin, and the repression of unfair competition."
  31. "Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property". http://www.wipo.int/treaties/en/ip/paris/index.html. 
  32. WIPO Intellectual Property Handbook: Policy, Law and Use. Chapter 2: Fields of Intellectual Property Protection WIPO 2008
  33. 33.0 33.1 "What is Intellectual Property?". http://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/intproperty/450/wipo_pub_450.pdf. 
  34. World Intellectual Property Organisation. "Understanding Copyright and Related Rights". WIPO. p. 8. http://www.wipo.int/freepublications/en/intproperty/909/wipo_pub_909.pdf. 
  35. "Trademark, Patent, or Copyright?". United States Patent and Trademark Office. Department of Commerce. 13 December 2015. http://www.uspto.gov/trademarks/basics/definitions.jsp. 
  36. "What is a trade mark (or brand)?". Intellectual Property Office. http://www.ipo.gov.uk/types/tm/t-about/t-whatis.htm. "A trade mark is a sign which can distinguish your goods and services from those of your competitors (you may refer to your trade mark as your "brand")." 
  37. "Trade Marks". Deutsches Patent- und Markenamt. 28 November 2014. http://www.patentamt.de/english/trade_marks/index.html. "Trade marks identify the goods and services of particular traders" 
  38. Merges, Robert P.; Menell, Peter S.; Lemley, Mark A. (2007). Intellectual Property in the New Technological Age (4th rev. ed.). New York: Wolters Kluwer. p. 29. ISBN 978-0-7355-6989-8. 
  39. Farah, Paolo Davide; Tremolada, Riccardo (15 March 2014). "Desirability of Commodification of Intangible Cultural Heritage: The Unsatisfying Role of Intellectual Property Rights". Transnational Dispute Management 11 (2). 
  40. Doris Schroeder and Peter Singer (May 2009). "Prudential Reasons for IPR Reform. A Report for Innova-P2". CAPPE, University of Melbourne. http://www.uclan.ac.uk/schools/school_of_health/research_projects/files/health_innova_IPR_reform_report.pdf. 
  41. "US Constitution". http://fairuse.stanford.edu/law/us-constitution/. 
  42. Levine, David; Michele Boldrin (7 September 2008). Against intellectual monopoly. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-87928-6. http://www.dklevine.com/papers/imbookfinalall.pdf. 
  43. Bollyky, Thomas (10 April 2013). "Why Chemotherapy That Costs $70,000 in the U.S. Costs $2,500 in India". The Atlantic. The Atlantic Monthly Group. https://www.theatlantic.com/health/archive/2013/04/why-chemotherapy-that-costs-70-000-in-the-us-costs-2-500-in-india/274847/. 
  44. Brassell, Martin; King, Kelvin (2013). Banking on IP?. Newport, Wales: The Intellectual Property Office. p. 15. ISBN 978-1-908908-86-5. http://www.ipo.gov.uk/ipresearch-bankingip.pdf. 
  45. "The Concept of Intellectual Property". WIPO Intellectual Property Handbook: Policy, Law and Use. p. 3. http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/about-ip/en/iprm/pdf/ch1.pdf. 
  46. "Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement". Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada. pp. 24. http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accords-commerciaux/assets/pdfs/acta-crc_apr15-2011_eng.pdf. 
  47. Shapiro, Robert J.; Pham, Nam D.; Blinder, Alan S. (July 2007). "Economic Effects of Intellectual Property-Intensive Manufacturing in the United States". Sonecon.com. World Growth. pp. 29. http://www.sonecon.com/docs/studies/0807_thevalueofip.pdf. 
  48. Shapiro, Robert; Pham, Nam; Blinder, Alan S. (July 2007). "Economic Effects of Intellectual Property-Intensive Manufacturing in the United States". the-value-of-ip.org. http://www.the-value-of-ip.org/. 
  49. "Measuring the Economic Impact of IP Systems". WIPO. 19 September 2007. http://www.wipo.int/portal/en/news/2007/article_0032.html. 
  50. "The Universal Declaration of Human Rights". United Nations. https://www.un.org/en/documents/udhr/index.shtml. 
  51. WIPO – The World Intellectual Property Organization. "Human Rights and Intellectual Property: An Overview". http://www.wipo.int/tk/en/hr/. 
  52. Moore, Adam (2014). "Intellectual Property". Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University. https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/intellectual-property/. 
  53. Ronald V. Bettig. "Critical Perspectives on the History and Philosophy of Copyright" in Copyrighting Culture: The Political Economy of Intellectual Property, by Ronald V. Bettig. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1996), 19–20
  54. Richard T. De George, "14. Intellectual Property Rights", in The Oxford Handbook of Business Ethics, by George G. Brenkert and Tom L. Beauchamp, vol. 1, 1st ed. (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, n.d.), 415–416.
  55. Richard T. De George, "14. Intellectual Property Rights", in The Oxford Handbook of Business Ethics, by George G. Brenkert and Tom L. Beauchamp, vol. 1, 1st ed. (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, n.d.), 416.
  56. 58.0 58.1 Spinello, Richard A. (January 2007). "Intellectual property rights". Library Hi Tech 25 (1): 12–22. doi:10.1108/07378830710735821. 
  57. Richard T. De George, "14. Intellectual Property Rights", in The Oxford Handbook of Business Ethics, by George G. Brenkert and Tom L. Beauchamp, vol. 1, 1st ed. (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, n.d.), 417.
  58. Richard T. De George, "14. Intellectual Property Rights", in The Oxford Handbook of Business Ethics, by George G. Brenkert and Tom L. Beauchamp, vol. 1, 1st ed. (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, n.d.), 418.
  59. The Law of Intellectual Property, Part 1 Chapter 1 Section 9 – Lysander Spooner
  60. Rand, Ayn (1967). Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal (paperback 2nd ed.). New York: Signet. ISBN 9780451147950. https://archive.org/details/capitalismunknow00rand. 
  61. 63.0 63.1 63.2 Miriam Bitton (2012) Rethinking the Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement's Criminal Copyright Enforcement Measures The Journal of Criminal Law & Criminology 102(1):67–117
  62. Ranjan, Prabhash (2022-07-17). "Russia-Ukraine War and WTO's National Security Exception" (in en). Foreign Trade Review 58 (2): 246–258. doi:10.1177/00157325221114586. ISSN 0015-7325. http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/00157325221114586. 
  63. Pearce, Joshua M. (2022). "Leveraging Intellectual Property to Prevent Nuclear War" (in en). Safety 8 (3): 55. doi:10.3390/safety8030055. ISSN 2313-576X. 
  64. Matthews, Duncan; Ostapenko, Hanna (2023-01-31). "The War in Ukraine Raises Questions About Patents for Secret Inventions" (in en). Queen Mary Law Research Paper (Rochester, NY). doi:10.2139/ssrn.4344212. https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=4344212. 
  65. Article 69 EPC
  66. Pradip K. Sahu and Shannon Mrksich, Ph.D. The Hatch-Waxman Act: When Is Research Exempt from Patent Infringement? ABA-IPL Newsletter 22(4) Summer 2004
  67. Matthew L. Cutler (2008) International Patent Litigation Survey: A Survey of the Characteristics of Patent Litigation in 17 International Jurisdictions
  68. Panethiere, Darrell (July–September 2005). "The Persistence of Piracy: The Consequences for Creativity, for Culture, and for Sustainable Development". UNESCO e-Copyright Bulletin. p. 2. http://portal.unesco.org/culture/en/files/28696/11513329261panethiere_en.pdf/panethiere_en.pdf. 
  69. "Copyright Basics". September 2021. https://www.copyright.gov/circs/circ01.pdf. 
  70. Correa, Carlos Maria; Li, Xuan (2009). Intellectual property enforcement: international perspectives. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 211. ISBN 978-1-84844-663-2. https://books.google.com/books?id=bN3o1uwpKF4C&q=copyright+infringement+international+acta. 
  71. 73.0 73.1 Irina D. Manta Spring 2011 The Puzzle of Criminal Sanctions for Intellectual Property Infringement Harvard Journal of Law & Technology 24(2):469–518
  72. 74.0 74.1 74.2 74.3 74.4 74.5 74.6 74.7 74.8 Cheng, Wenting (2023). China in Global Governance of Intellectual Property: Implications for Global Distributive Justice. Palgrave Socio-Legal Studies series. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-3-031-24369-1. 
  73. "If Intellectual Property Is Neither Intellectual, Nor Property, What Is It?". Techdirt. 6 March 2008. https://www.techdirt.com/articles/20080306/003240458/if-intellectual-property-is-neither-intellectual-property-what-is-it.shtml. 
  74. Stallman, Richard M.. "Did You Say "Intellectual Property"? It's a Seductive Mirage". Free Software Foundation, Inc.. https://www.gnu.org/philosophy/not-ipr.en.html. 
  75. Stallman, Richard M.. "Words to Avoid (or Use with Care) Because They Are Loaded or Confusing". The GNU Project. https://www.gnu.org/philosophy/words-to-avoid.en.html#IntellectualProperty. 
  76. Boldrin, Michele, and David K. Levine. Against intellectual monopoly . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
  77. "A Model of Discovery". http://levine.sscnet.ucla.edu/papers/aea_pp09.pdf. 
  78. Stallman, Richard (19 April 2001). "copyright and globalization in the age of computer networks". http://web.mit.edu/comm-forum/forums/copyright.html. 
  79. Stallman, Richard. "Misinterpreting Copyright". https://www.gnu.org/philosophy/misinterpreting-copyright.html. 
  80. 82.0 82.1 "Against perpetual copyright". http://wiki.lessig.org/index.php/Against_perpetual_copyright. 
  81. Doctorow, Cory (21 February 2008). ""Intellectual property" is a silly euphemism". The Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2008/feb/21/intellectual.property. 
  82. Stephan Kinsella (2001) Against Intellectual Property Journal of Libertarian Studies 15(2):1–53
  83. "Language Matters: Framing The Copyright Monopoly So We Can Keep Our Liberties". 14 July 2013. http://torrentfreak.com/language-matters-framing-the-copyright-monopoly-so-we-can-keep-our-liberties-130714/. 
  84. "1984+30: GNU speech to defeat e-newspeak". http://www.fsfla.org/~lxoliva/fsfla/1984+30.en.pdf. 
  85. Stephan Kinsella for Ludwig von Mises Institute blog, 6 January 2011. Intellectual Poverty
  86. Official drm.info site run by the Free Software Foundation Europe (FSFE)
  87. "What is DRM?". Defective by Design. http://www.defectivebydesign.org/what_is_drm_digital_restrictions_management. 
  88. Birgitte Andersen. "'Intellectual Property Right' Or 'Intellectual Monopoly Privilege: Which One Should Patent Analysts Focus On?" CONFERENCIA INTERNACIONAL SOBRE SISTEMAS DE INOVAÇÃO E ESTRATÉGIAS DE DESENVOLVIMENTO PARA O TERCEIRO MILÊNIO. Nov 2003
  89. Martin, G; Sorenson, C; Faunce, TA (2007). "Balancing intellectual monopoly privileges and the need for essential medicines". Globalization and Health 3 (1): 4. doi:10.1186/1744-8603-3-4. PMID 17565684. "Balancing the need to protect the intellectual property rights (IPRs) (which the third author considers are more accurately described as intellectual monopoly privileges (IMPs)) of pharmaceutical companies, with the need to ensure access to essential medicines in developing countries is one of the most pressing challenges facing international policy makers today.". 
  90. Birgitte Andersen. 'Intellectual Property Right' Or 'Intellectual Monopoly Privilege': Which One Should Patent Analysts Focus On? Conferência Internacional Sobre Sistemas De Inovação E Estratégias De Desenvolvimento Para O Terceiro Milênio. Nov. 2003
  91. Martin, G; Sorenson, C; Faunce, TA (2007). "Editorial: Balancing the need to protect the intellectual property rights (IPRs)". Globalization and Health 3 (1): 4. doi:10.1186/1744-8603-3-4. PMID 17565684. 
  92. On patents – Daniel B. Ravicher (6 August 2008). "Protecting Freedom In The Patent System: The Public Patent Foundation's Mission and Activities". https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=d0chez_Jf5A. 
  93. Stiglitz, Joseph (13 October 2006). "Authors@Google: Joseph Stiglitz – Making Globalization Work.". https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=UzhD7KVs-R4#t=16m05s. 
  94. Stallman's got company: Researcher wants nanotech patent moratorium – Ars Technica
  95. Freeze on nanotechnology patents proposed to help grow the sector - Wired UK 23 Nov 2012
  96. Moser, Petra. 2013. "Patents and Innovation: Evidence from Economic History." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1): 23–44.
  97. Baten, Jörg; Bianchi, Nicola; Moser, Petra (2017). "Compulsory licensing and innovation–Historical evidence from German patents after WWI". Journal of Development Economics 126: 231–242. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2017.01.002. 
  98. Peter Drahos and John Braithwaite. Information Feudalism: Who Owns the Knowledge Economy?, Earthscan 2002
  99. WIPO – World Intellectual Property Organization. "Human Rights and Intellectual Property: An Overview". http://www.wipo.int/tk/en/hr/. 
  100. Staff, UN Committee on Economic Social and Cultural Rights. Geneva, 12–30 November 2001. Human rights and intellectual property
  101. Chapman, Audrey R. (December 2002). "The Human Rights Implications of Intellectual Property Protection". Journal of International Economic Law 5 (4): 861–882. doi:10.1093/jiel/5.4.861. 
  102. The Geneva Declaration on the Future of the World Intellectual Property Organization
  103. 105.0 105.1 Sonderholm, Jorn (2010). "Ethical Issues Surrounding Intellectual Property Rights". Philosophy Compass 5 (12): 1107–1115. doi:10.1111/j.1747-9991.2010.00358.x. 
  104. D'Amato, David. "Libertarian Views of Intellectual Property: Rothbard, Tucker, Spooner, and Rand". Cato Institute. https://www.libertarianism.org/columns/libertarian-views-intellectual-property-rothbard-tucker-spooner-rand. 
  105. Stephan Kinsella, "What It Means To Be an Anarcho-Capitalist", "LewRockwell.com", published 2004-01-20, archived 15 April 2018. Retrieved 4 August 2018.
  106. N. Stephan Kinsella, Against Intellectual property (2008), p. 44.
  107. Thomas Jefferson, Letter to Isaac McPherson (August 13, 1813)
  108. Boyle, James (14 October 2005). "Protecting the public domain". The Guardian.
  109. Bennet, Philip (2009). Native Americans and Intellectual Property: the Necessity of Implementing Collective Ideals into Current United States Intellectual Property Laws. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1498783. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1498783. 
  110. Dariusz Jemielniak; Aleksandra Przegalinska (18 February 2020). Collaborative Society. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-35645-9. https://books.google.com/books?id=yLDMDwAAQBAJ. 
  111. Fiesler, Casey; Feuston, Jessica L.; Bruckman, Amy S. (28 February 2015). "Understanding Copyright Law in Online Creative Communities". Proceedings of the 18th ACM Conference on Computer Supported Cooperative Work & Social Computing. CSCW '15. Vancouver, BC, Canada: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 116–129. doi:10.1145/2675133.2675234. ISBN 978-1-4503-2922-4. https://doi.org/10.1145/2675133.2675234. 
  112. Freund, Katharina (1 August 2016). ""Fair use is legal use": Copyright negotiations and strategies in the fan-vidding community" (in en). New Media & Society 18 (7): 1347–1363. doi:10.1177/1461444814555952. ISSN 1461-4448. https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444814555952. 
  113. Allen, Peter James (24 August 2008). "Rip, mix, burn ... sue ... ad infinitum: The effects of deterrence vs voluntary cooperation on non-commercial online copyright infringing behaviour" (in en). First Monday. doi:10.5210/fm.v13i9.2073. ISSN 1396-0466. https://journals.uic.edu/ojs/index.php/fm/article/view/2073. 
  114. Council for Responsible Genetics, "DNA Patents Create Monopolies on Living Organisms". Retrieved 2008.12.18.
  115. Plant Patents USPTO.gov
  116. E.g., the U.S. Copyright Term Extension Act, Pub.L. 105–298.
  117. Mark Helprin, Op-ed: A Great Idea Lives Forever. Shouldn't Its Copyright? The New York Times, 20 May 2007.
  118. Eldred v. Ashcroft Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U. S. 186 (2003)
  119. Masnick, Mike (21 May 2007). "Arguing For Infinite Copyright... Using Copied Ideas And A Near Total Misunderstanding Of Property". http://www.techdirt.com/articles/20070521/015928.shtml. 
  120. Library of Congress Copyright Office Docket No. 2012–12 Orphan Works and Mass Digitization Federal Register, Vol. 77, No. 204. Monday, 22 October 2012. Notices. PP 64555–64561; see p 64555 first column for international efforts and 3rd column for description of the problem.
  121. Dennis Wharton, "MPAA's Rebel With Cause Fights for Copyright Coin", Variety (3 August 1992), Vol. 348, No. 2, p. 18.
  122. William W. Fisher III, The Growth of Intellectual Property:A History of the Ownership of Ideas in the United States Eigentumskulturen im Vergleich (Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 1999)
  123. Smith, Brett (2007–2010). "A Quick Guide to GPLv3". Free Software Foundation. https://www.gnu.org/licenses/quick-guide-gplv3.en.html. 
  124. Katherine Beckman and Christa Pletcher (2009) Expanding Global Trademark Regulation Wake Forest Intellectual Property Law Journal 10(2): 215–239
  125. Toplensky, Rochelle (11 March 2018). "Multinationals pay lower taxes than a decade ago". Financial Times. https://www.ft.com/content/2b356956-17fc-11e8-9376-4a6390addb44. 
  126. "Intellectual Property and Tax Avoidance in Ireland". Fordham Intellectual Property, Media & Entertainment Law Journal. 30 August 2016. http://www.fordhamiplj.org/2016/08/30/ip-tax-avoidance-ireland/. 
  127. Intellectual property (IP) has become the leading tax-avoidance vehicle."Intellectual Property Law Solutions to Tax Avoidance". UCLA Law Review. 2015. https://www.uclalawreview.org/pdf/62-1-1.pdf. 
  128. "Patently problematic". The Economist. August 2015. https://www.economist.com/business/2015/08/27/patently-problematic. 
  129. "Intellectual Property Tax Planning in the light of Base Erosion and Profit Shifting". University of Tilburg. June 2017. http://arno.uvt.nl/show.cgi?fid=143915. 
  130. "Profit Shifting and "Aggressive" Tax Planning by Multinational Firms". Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW). October 2013. p. 3. http://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp13078.pdf. 
  131. 133.0 133.1 "BEPS Project Background Brief". OECD. January 2017. http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/background-brief-inclusive-framework-for-beps-implementation.pdf. 
  132. "A Hybrid Approach: The Treatment of Foreign Profits under the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act". Tax Foundation. 3 May 2018. https://taxfoundation.org/treatment-foreign-profits-tax-cuts-jobs-act/. 
  133. "Trump's US tax reform a significant challenge for Ireland". The Irish Times. 30 November 2017. https://www.irishtimes.com/business/economy/trump-s-us-tax-reform-a-significant-challenge-for-ireland-1.3310866. 
  134. "Donald Trump singles out Ireland in tax speech". The Irish Times. 29 November 2017. https://www.irishtimes.com/business/donald-trump-singles-out-ireland-in-tax-speech-1.3310149?mode=sample&auth-failed=1&pw-origin=https%3A%2F%2Fwww.irishtimes.com%2Fbusiness%2Fdonald-trump-singles-out-ireland-in-tax-speech-1.3310149. 
  135. "Why Ireland faces a fight on the corporate tax front". The Irish Times. 14 March 2018. https://www.irishtimes.com/business/economy/why-ireland-faces-a-fight-on-the-corporate-tax-front-1.3426080. 
  136. "EU digital levy could hit tech FDI and tax revenue here". Irish Independent. 21 March 2018. https://www.independent.ie/business/irish/eu-digital-levy-could-hit-tech-fdi-and-tax-revenue-here-36725944.html. 
  137. "What the EU's new taxes on the tech giants mean – and how they would hurt Ireland". thejournal.ie. 24 March 2018. http://www.thejournal.ie/eu-digital-tax-ireland-2-2-3918628-Mar2018/. 
  138. "New UN tax handbook: Lower-income countries vs OECD BEPS failure". Tax Justice Network. 11 September 2017. https://www.taxjustice.net/2017/09/11/new-un-tax-handbook-sets-lower-income-countries-oecd-beps/. 
  139. WIPO, World Intellectual Property Organization (8 March 2021). "Gender Equality, Diversity and Intellectual Property". https://www.wipo.int/women-and-ip/en/. 
  140. WIPO, World Intellectual Property Organization (21 May 2021). "Closing the Gender Gap in IP". https://www.wipo.int/women-and-ip/en/news/2021/news_0005.html. 

Sources

  • Arai, Hisamitsu. "Intellectual Property Policies for the Twenty-First Century: The Japanese Experience in Wealth Creation", WIPO Publication Number 834 (E). 2000. wipo.int
  • Bettig, R. V. (1996). Critical Perspectives on the History and Philosophy of Copyright. In R. V. Bettig, Copyrighting Culture: The Political Economy of Intellectual Property. (pp. 9–32). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
  • Boldrin, Michele and David K. Levine. "Against Intellectual Monopoly", 2008. dkleving.com
  • Hahn, Robert W., Intellectual Property Rights in Frontier Industries: Software and Biotechnology, AEI Press, March 2005.
  • Branstetter, Lee, Raymond Fishman and C. Fritz Foley. "Do Stronger Intellectual Property Rights Increase International Technology Transfer? Empirical Evidence from US Firm-Level Data". NBER Working Paper 11516. July 2005. weblog.ipcentral.info
  • Connell, Shaun. "Intellectual Ownership". October 2007. rebithofffreedom.org
  • De George, Richard T. "14. Intellectual Property Rights." In The Oxford Handbook of Business Ethics, by George G. Brenkert and Tom L. Beauchamp, 1:408–439. 1st ed. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, n.d.
  • Farah, Paolo and Cima, Elena. "China's Participation in the World Trade Organization: Trade in Goods, Services, Intellectual Property Rights and Transparency Issues" in Aurelio Lopez-Tarruella Martinez (ed.), El comercio con China. Oportunidades empresariales, incertidumbres jurídicas, Tirant lo Blanch, Valencia (Spain) 2010, pp. 85–121. ISBN:978-84-8456-981-7. Available at SSRN.com
  • Farah, Paolo Davide, Tremolada Riccardo, Desirability of Commodification of Intangible Cultural Heritage: The Unsatisfying Role of IPRs, in TRANSNATIONAL DISPUTE MANAGEMENT, Special Issues "The New Frontiers of Cultural Law: Intangible Heritage Disputes", Volume 11, Issue 2, March 2014, ISSN 1875-4120 Available at SSRN.com
  • Farah, Paolo Davide, Tremolada Riccardo, Intellectual Property Rights, Human Rights and Intangible Cultural Heritage, Journal of Intellectual Property Law, Issue 2, Part I, June 2014, ISSN 0035-614X, Giuffre, pp. 21–47. Available at SSRN.com
  • Goldstein, Paul; Reese, R. Anthony (2008). Copyright, Patent, Trademark and Related State Doctrines: Cases and Materials on the Law of Intellectual Property (6th ed.). New York: Foundation Press. ISBN 978-1-59941-139-2. 
  • Gowers, Andrew. "Gowers Review of Intellectual Property". Her Majesty's Treasury, November 2006. hm-treasury.gov.uk ISBN:978-0-11-840483-9.
  • Greenhalgh, C. & Rogers M., (2010). Innovation, Intellectual Property, and Economic Growth. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
  • Kinsella, Stephan. "Against Intellectual Property". Journal of Libertarian Studies 15.2 (Spring 2001): 1–53. mises.org
  • Lai, Edwin. "The Economics of Intellectual Property Protection in the Global Economy". Princeton University. April 2001. dklevine.com
  • Lee, Richmond K. Scope and Interplay of IP Rights Accralaw offices.
  • Lessig, Lawrence. "Free Culture: How Big Media Uses Technology and the Law to Lock Down Culture and Control Creativity". New York: Penguin Press, 2004. free-culture.cc .
  • Lindberg, Van. Intellectual Property and Open Source: A Practical Guide to Protecting Code. O'Reilly Books, 2008. ISBN:0-596-51796-3 | ISBN:978-0-596-51796-0
  • Maskus, Keith E. "Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Development". Case Western Reserve Journal of International Law, Vol. 32, 471. journals/jil/32-3/maskusarticle.pdf law.case.edu
  • Mazzone, Jason. "Copyfraud". Brooklyn Law School, Legal Studies Paper No. 40. New York University Law Review 81 (2006): 1027. (Abstract.)
  • Miller, Arthur Raphael, and Michael H. Davis. Intellectual Property: Patents, Trademarks, and Copyright. 3rd ed. New York: West/Wadsworth, 2000. ISBN:0-314-23519-1.
  • Moore, Adam, "Intellectual Property", The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2011 Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.),
  • Morin, Jean-Frédéric, Paradigm Shift in the Global IP Regime: The Agency of Academics, Review of International Political Economy, vol. 21(2), 2014, pp. 275–309.
  • Mossoff, A. 'Rethinking the Development of Patents: An Intellectual History, 1550–1800,' Hastings Law Journal, Vol. 52, p. 1255, 2001
  • Rozanski, Felix. "Developing Countries and Pharmaceutical Intellectual Property Rights: Myths and Reality" stockholm-network.org
  • Perelman, Michael. Steal This Idea: Intellectual Property and The Corporate Confiscation of Creativity. Palgrave Macmillan, 2004.
  • Rand, Ayn. "Patents and Copyrights" in Ayn Rand, ed. 'Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal,' New York: New American Library, 1966, pp. 126–128
  • Reisman, George. 'Capitalism: A Complete & Integrated Understanding of the Nature & Value of Human Economic Life,' Ottawa, Illinois: 1996, pp. 388–389
  • Schechter, Roger E., and John R. Thomas. Intellectual Property: The Law of Copyrights, Patents and Trademarks. New York: West/Wadsworth, 2003, ISBN:0-314-06599-7.
  • Schneider, Patricia H. "International Trade, Economic Growth and Intellectual Property Rights: A Panel Data Study of Developed and Developing Countries". July 2004. mtholyoke.edu
  • Shapiro, Robert and Nam Pham. "Economic Effects of Intellectual Property-Intensive Manufacturing in the United States". July 2007. the-value-of.ip.org. Retrieved 2008-04-09.
  • Spooner, Lysander. "The Law of Intellectual Property; or An Essay on the Right of Authors and Inventors to a Perpetual Property in their Ideas". Boston: Bela Marsh, 1855.
  • Vaidhyanathan, Siva. The Anarchist in the Library: How the Clash Between Freedom and Control Is Hacking the Real World and Crashing the System. New York: Basic Books, 2004.
  • Burk, Dan L.; Mark A. Lemley (2009). The Patent Crisis and How the Courts Can Solve It. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-08061-1. 

External links




Licensed under CC BY-SA 3.0 | Source: https://handwiki.org/wiki/Social:Intellectual_property
13 views | Status: cached on August 11 2024 09:13:51
↧ Download this article as ZWI file
Encyclosphere.org EncycloReader is supported by the EncyclosphereKSF