Poverty

From RationalWiki - Reading time: 15 min

Traffic cone.png Under Construction:
This article is currently receiving a major revamp by GeeJayK. Please do not edit it while this template is up. However, feel free to offer input on the talk page.
If this template is up for more than a few weeks without activity, you may remove it.
A homeless man in Paris, France.
The dismal science
Economics
Icon economics.svg
Economic systems

  $  Free market
  €  Social democracy
  ☭ Socialist economy

Major concepts
The worldly philosophers
The idea that the poor should have leisure has always been shocking to the rich.
Bertrand Russell[1]:17

Poverty is the inability to provide for one's well-being — that is, being too poor to obtain adequate food, shelter, clothing, or healthcare.

Categorizing poverty[edit]

There are many ways to categorize poverty. Here are some of the most common:

Relative poverty[edit]

Relative poverty is judged by local standards. I.e., someone with a medium sized house, a decent car and a good wage may not be poor, per se, but they would be relatively poor if they lived in an estate full of millionaires and all the nearby shops were suited to those super rich. Or, as economist John Kenneth Galbraith wrote, "People are poverty stricken when their income, even if adequate for survival, falls markedly behind that of their community."[2]:577 Individual countries will have their own official "poverty lines" (often called "bread lines") which people can live above or below.[3]

Extreme poverty[edit]

Not all poverty is the same, and some poor people are even worse off. Extreme poverty is defined as surviving on less than $2.15 per person per day at 2017, the so-called the International Poverty LineWikipedia (IPL).[4] This is a situation where not only people don't have enough to live a dignified life: they often face immediate risk of death by starvation.

While being widely used, the method of using the IPL to calculare extreme poverty has seen some criticism too. A study published in 2024 by the Nature journal, for instance, claimed that the IPL resulting statistics does not perform acceptably well in terms of accuracy and precision, while arguing that adoption of alternative methods for monitoring global poverty should be considered.[5] Another limitation of this method is the fact that that there's often a gap between national poverty lines and the IPL.[6]

Multidimensional poverty[edit]

While income means a lot, it doesn't mean everything. The Multidimensional Poverty IndexWikipedia (MPI) was created in 2010 by the United Nations, along with the University of Oxford, to use a wide ranger of indicators in order to measure poverty. The indicators are health (measured by nutrition and child mortality, education (measured by years of schooling and school attendance) and living standards (measured by cooking fuel, sanitation, drinking water, electricity, housing and assets).[7]

Taking inspiration in the MPI, the World Bank also created their "Multidimensional Poverty Measure", focusing on income, education and access to basic infrastructure.[8]

Disparities[edit]

While Asia managed to tackle extreme poverty very quickly in the last few decades, sub-Saharan Africa still has a long way to go.

The distribution of poverty is very uneven:

  • In 2021, more than 50 per cent of the Saharan African population was multidimensionally poor. South Asia also had a very high rate of multidimensional poverty, around 30 per cent, though it's dropping faster.[9]
  • Poverty is also correlated with age, with the youth being generally poorer. In 2022, children were more than twice as likely as adults to live in extreme poverty. They comprised more than half of those living in extreme poverty, while their share of the population was 31 percent.[10] In 2019, around 50 per cent of the world's multidimensional poor were under the age of 18 years of age while 75 per cent are under 40.[11]
  • There are more poor women than poor men. In 2022, around 383 million women and girls lived in extreme poverty compared to 368 million men and boys.[12]
  • Rural areas are generally poorer. In 2021, about 80 per cent of those living below the poverty line lived in rural areas. In the same year, 20 per cent of rural people lived in extreme poverty. The rate for urban areas is around 5 per cent.[13]
  • National data on income poverty disaggregated by disability remain scarce, but available data shows that the proportion of persons with disabilities living under the national or international poverty line was in some countries twice as high as that of persons without disabilities.[14]

Historical trends[edit]

Last Belongings by Aleksander KotsisWikipedia. Painted 1870.

The Malthusian era[edit]

See the main article on this topic: Thomas Malthus

From the Neolithic Revolution to the Industrial Revolution very little happened. Many studies[15][16][17] have shown that human life in the whole world was, for most people, as Thomas Hobbes wrote on his Leviathan, “solitary, poore, nasty, brutish, and short”.[18]:192

Why was the world so poor back then? The best explanation was perhaps posited by the economist and cleric Thomas Malthus: Let’s imagine a pre-industrial age village where the inhabitants devise a more efficient way to grow their crops, increasing their ability to produce food. At first, the villagers’ diets would improve as they would be able to eat more. Moreover, it is possible that they would be able to trade their surplus. It is even possible that the abundance of food might enable them to reduce their work and have more leisure. As a result, their living conditions would rise. Nonetheless, such surplus, Malthus argued, would allow them to sustain more children. The village’s population would then grow. As the land available for cultivation within the village is necessarily limited, this population growth would gradually result in a reduction in village’s food surplus. Living standards would then begin to drop after the initial rise that we saw and would only stop falling once the ratio of food per person returned to its original level. In other words, the technological progress would, in the long term, lead to a larger population, but not a richer one.[19]:28-30

The Great Divergence[edit]

However, in the late 18th century and especially in 19th century, some countries managed to break the mold. It started in the UK, then it spread to the Northern Europe, also reaching the United States and finally Japan. The accumulation of physical and human capital, and especially technological progress, became exponential and allowed the labour productivityWikipedia to skyrocket, making some countries escape from the Malthusian trap.[19]:27-41 It wasn’t, of course, the first time that a society managed to innovate and raise productivity. These efflorescences, however, ended up with the creation of new institutions that developed another inertial state where technological innovation slowed, and economic and political elites sought to defend existing social patterns.[20] For the first time in human history, there was self-sustained, stable economic growth and improvements in the quality of life.

This growth was, at least at first, however, extremely uneven, being confined in a few countries. Throughout most of the human history, the gap between the rich and the poor was never so wide. After the Industrial Revolution, even a poor westerner tended to be richer than the average person living elsewhere. In 1820, the G7Wikipedia share of global income soared from 20 per cent to over 60 per cent in 1990.[21] This growth disparity is called by historians and economists as the “Great DivergenceWikipedia”.

Convergence?[edit]

It’s true that some countries in Asia and especially in Africa still have a lower income per capita than the UK had over 200 years ago.[22]:2 However, the last decades of the second half of the 20th century finally saw much of the rest of the world taking off, and inequality between countries dropped for the first time since the Industrial Revolution.[23][24][25] The Multidimensional Poverty Index found that 25 countries managed to halve multidimensional poverty between 2007 and 2022, with populous Asian countries such as China, Indonesia and above all India, doing much of the work.[note 1][26] This reversal has been called “The Great Convergence” by analysts and scholars.[27][28][29][30]

The future[edit]

While the last decades saw the sharp rises in the standards of living, poverty (including extreme poverty) will probably still remain a major problem in the next years. A UNU-WIDERWikipedia report predicted that, in 2030 over 600 million people in the world will remain in extreme poverty, while 665 million people will still be undernourished, with many other problems, such as the lack of access to clean water and basic sanitation still prominent in sub-Saharan Africa and low-income countries.[31] Longer term forecasts are more optimistic, with one study claiming that extreme poverty may finally be eradicated by 2050, spurred by economic growth in low-income countries.[32]

Causes of poverty and keys to development[edit]

Once one starts to think about them, it is hard to think about anything else.
—Nobel Memorial Laureate economist Robert E. LucasWikipedia on the causes of development.[33]

Northwestern Europe was behind other parts of the rest of Eurasia for centuries following the fall of the Western Roman Empire, so it's hard to claim that the Western economic dominance was inevitable.[22]:130 This of course raises some questions. Why did the the Great Divergence start in Northwestern Europe, especially in Britain? Why not Southern Europe, which dominated the continent's economy for centuries before the Industrial Revolution instead? Or China which was technologically dominant until around 1500? Why didn't the pace of innovation slow down, as occurred in prior growth spurts around the world? And more importantly, can other countries do the same? All these questions are still subject to much controversy, but there are some answers.

Geography[edit]

See the main article on this topic: Geographic determinism
The West rules because of geography.
—Historian and archaeologist Ian Morris on the rise of the Western world.[34]:557

Geography is a pessimistic explanation to development. After all, geography doesn't change a lot as plate tectonics are very slow. And yet, the richest places on Earth have changed. When the Romans conquered Britain, the local people were living in a situation close to the Stone Age, but the Industrial Revolution started there. While geography is important, there might be something else.

Culture[edit]

See the main article on this topic: Culture

According to Harvard anthropologist Joseph Henrich, culture is defined by the body of practices, techniques, heuristics, tools, motivations, values, and beliefs that everyone acquires while growing up, usually by learning from other others around you.[35]:3 Culture is a relatively old explanation for disparities between rich and poor nations, being advanced, for instance, by the sociologist Max Weber on his famous book The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, first published in 1904.

More recent studies have claimed that values such as praising hard work, risk taking, and wealth accumulation were essential for northwestern Europe's take-off in the 17th and 18th centuries. According to proponents of this idea, one of the primary impediments to development in history was the way people thought and talked about work and profit, and how a society that frowns upon hard work will be unlikely to have a meaninful number of innovators. For the ancient Greeks and Romans, for instance, if you were successful, you were supposed to strive to own a landed estate and live off of its returns, and work of any type was one of the the lowest-valued pursuits. Wealth was only valued when it could permitted leisure. Cultural values that disparaged hard work persisted during the Middle Ages among the European elite.[22]:68-9

Just like geography, culture is hard to change. As anthropologists Peter J. Richerson and Robert Boyd describe it: “[T]he wheels of cultural evolution roll on the time scale of millennia, even though, when we look closely at any one society over short periods of time, change is often readily perceptible.”[36] So, for the same reasons as geography, while culture can play an important role, it can't be the only explanation of development.

Insititutions[edit]

When the state is without the Way, being rich and eminent is a cause for shame.
Confucius[37]:56
The United States Congress: electoral democracies, in general, fare better than autocracies.

According to the Nobel Memorial Prize laureate economic historian Douglass North, institutions are "humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic, and social interaction. They consist of both informal constraints (sanctions, taboos, customs, traditions, and codes of conduct), and formal rules (constitutions, laws, property rights".[38] Saying that political, legal and economic institutions matter seems to be obvious to most people. A better question is, which institutions foster development. The division of the North Korea and the South Korea was almost a controlled experiment. The disparities between the two countries are neither the result of geographical or cultural differences, as, for most of the past centuries, the Korean Peninsula largely formed a single social entity, whose inhabitants shared a common language and culture. North Korea’s poverty and technological underdevelopment, just like that of East Germany prior to the fall of the Berlin Wall, originates in political and economic institutions that restricted personal and economic freedoms. The lack of constraints on government power, the absence of the rule of law, the insecure property rights, along with the inherently inefficient central planning, have hindered entrepreneurship and innovation, while encouraging corruption and fostering poverty.[19]:144 It is no surprise that the South Korea income per capita is many times higher than the one in North Korea,[39] with differences in other indicators, such as life expectancy, being just as drastic.[40] But why do liberal democracies tend to do better at development? Basically, they tend to invest more on public goods related to healthcare and schooling, reduce social unrest, and especially, they enact economic reforms better than nondemocracies.[41]

Extractive elites aren't always part of the government and sometimes arise from the rest of the society. It is important that the institution and the rules of the game are be the same for everyone. The way Bill Gates and the Carlos SlimWikipedia became two of the richest men in the world mirrors the difference between the institutions in the US and in Mexico. Slim didn't become rich by innovation, but by his political connections. He bought the privatized Telmex not by paying out of his pocket, but by using dividends of the Telmex itself to pay for the stock. Attempts to challenge his monopoly in his country failed. Meanwhile, Gates' Microsoft had a hard time for its abuses of anti-competitive practices and monopoly power, even if less than some people demanded.[42]:39-40

But how institutions emerge? There is no defining answer to that question, which doesn’t mean that history can’t teach us anything about them.

Institutions are, of course, often imposed by the government. The Meiji Restoration, for instance, saw Japan adopting many Western institutions. In the first five years after the revolution, Japan created and adopted institutions such as a prefectorial system of administration, a postal system, a daily newspaper, conscription, its first railway, religious toleration and the Gregorian calendar. A representative system of local government was inaugurated in 1879, and ten years later a new constitution set up a bicameral parliament.[43] :843 Japan didn't copy only "good" institutions though: they also tried to copy European colonialism and imperialism, believing it was a good thing,[44], showing that just copying institutions is not that easy since we often don't know what are the good and bad institutions. Speaking of colonialism, it is possible from a foreign power to impose institutions in another nation – and those imposed institutions can still explain aspects of poverty and wealth in many countries around the world. We can contrast, for instance, the institutions perpetuated by the Spanish conquistadors, such as the Mit'aWikipedia, with colonies such as the US and Australia, that inherited the English legal system, and became some of the richest nations in the world.[45]:152-54 In Africa, however, British rule was very different, imposing many extractive institutions that hung on and often grew stronger after independence.[42]:336

A more evolutionary way of developing institutions is by spontaneous orderWikipedia. This comes to the notion that no group of individuals knows enough to plan and devise institutions – but society might have enough information to do so. Institutions should arise, according to proponents of this perspective, not by human design, but by human action.[46]:96 The most obvious example of this is the language. No one designed the most widespread languages in the world, they evolve alone, but they work very well as forms of communication, and spelling reforms are relatively uncommon. This, according to the Austrian School economist and philosopher Friedrich Hayek, also applies to the legal system. The role of the lawmaker, as Hayek said in his Nobel lecture, is “not to shape the results as the craftsman shapes his handiwork, but rather to cultivate a growth by providing the appropriate environment, in the manner in which the gardener does this for his plants.”[47] In other words, institutions can emerge organically through the interactions of individuals within a society, rather than being imposed top-down by a centralized authority. While this strong emphasis on the common law might have fell out of favor, it was very frequent throughout history. The seminal Code of Hammurabi was declaration of existing law that Hammurabi assembled, but not created.[43]:63-64. This is also the case of the Draco's code in Athens and the Twelve Tables in Rome.[48]:143 According to legal scholar Patrick Atiyah, before the Reform Act of 1832 in England, most people considered that law was not something “made”, but something that was “there”, waiting interpretation, that didn’t really need constant change.[49]:96

Finally, sometimes crucial institutions even appear by accidents that can hardly be controlled by humans. The Black Death, despite its catastrophic results, is often regarded as one of the reasons for the rise of the England and the Western Europe. By wiping out around half of the population, the plague shook the foundations of the British feudalism, creating a massive scarcity of labor, encouraging peasants to demand changes, such as higher wages, allowing the region to escape from the feudal order.[42]:98 And why didn’t the same thing happen in Russia and Eastern Europe, places where the Black Death also hit hard? Because in Eastern Europe towns were weaker and less populous, so peasants had less options and places to go, while lords were better organized. As a result, Western Europe broke the sefdom cycle, while forced labor became even more prominent in Eastern Europe.[50]

While it is still hard to change institutions, it's probably easier to change them during a human lifespan than culture and geography, such as South Korea shows, and the results can be astonishing.[note 2] Nonetheless, even though institutions are beyond important, even them can't explain everything. Italy has been a single country for well over a century, with all regions having, at least in theory, a the same legal framework. And yet, the Southern italy is much poorer than Northern Italy. Some scholars have argued that this gap could be explained in part because of cultural differences, such as trust levels been lower in the south.[51] Others have, however argued that there are meaningful institutional differences between the two regions.[52] Another refutation to the institution explanation is China. Once one of the poorest countries in the world, China saw its living standards rise fast in the last few decades,[note 3] and this only happened after the country adopted many institutions that, in theory at least, enact development, such as privatization, a civil codeWikipedia with elements of the German law and relative respect for property rights.[22]:218 But it didn't adopt all of them, still being a dictatorship, and its respect to property rights still leaves much to be desired when compared with countries that didn't grow so fast. And while the Chinese economy has faltered after the covid-19 pandemic,[55] it's still seemingly in better shape than proponents of the institutional explanation such as the MIT economist Daron Acemoglu, who predicted in 2012 on his book Why Nations Fail, almost a decade before the pandemic start, a huge slowdown on China.[42]:462

Demographics[edit]

See the main article on this topic: Demographics

Conclusions[edit]

See also[edit]

Notes[edit]

  1. The index still claims that a over a billion people still struggle with poverty nonetheless.
  2. The South Korean example, despite being inspiring, is not perfect: much of the institutions that fostered the South Korean miracle were imposed by a brutal dictatorship. It also comes without saying that there are trade-offs, and South Korea does face many problems today.
  3. The reliability of the Chinese statistics has been questioned before, and it's now often seen just as a reference point.[53] Nonetheless, their data don't seem to be more egregious than other developing countries.[54]

References[edit]

  1. In Praise of Idleness and Other Essays by Bertrand Russell (1935) George Allen & Unwin.
  2. Galbraith, John Kenneth (2010). The affluent society and other writings, 1952-1967. The Library of America. New York: Library of America : Distributed to the trade in the U.S. by Penguin Group (USA). ISBN 978-1-59853-077-3. OCLC 548596968. 
  3. See the Wikipedia article on Poverty threshold.
  4. dpicampaigns. "Goal 1: End poverty in all its forms everywhere" (in en-US). 
  5. Moatsos, Michail; Lazopoulos, Achillefs (2024-07-16). "Stress-testing the international poverty line and the official global poverty statistics" (in en). Humanities and Social Sciences Communications 11 (1): 1–12. doiWikipedia:10.1057/s41599-024-03260-6. ISSN 2662-9992. 
  6. Nilsen, Alf Gunvald (2018-10-17). "Why the World Bank’s optimism about global poverty misses the point" (in en-US). 
  7. Nations, United (2023-07-11) (in en). 2023 Global Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) (Report). United Nations. 
  8. "Multidimensional Poverty Measure" (in en). 
  9. "Inequalities between ethnic groups are stark, new UN report reveals | UN News" (in en). 2021-10-07. 
  10. "Global Trends in Child Monetary Poverty According to International Poverty Lines" (in en). 
  11. Matters, Development (2019-03-14). "5 facts about global poverty that may surprise you" (in en-US). 
  12. "Progress on the Sustainable Development Goals: The gender snapshot 2022" (in en). 2021-09-17. 
  13. United Nations. "World Social Report 2021" (in en). 
  14. "Ending poverty and hunger for all persons with disabilities | United Nations Enable". 
  15. Fouquet, Roger; Broadberry, Stephen (2015-11). "Seven Centuries of European Economic Growth and Decline" (in en). Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 (4): 227–244. doiWikipedia:10.1257/jep.29.4.227. ISSN 0895-3309. 
  16. "Maddison Project Database 2020" (in en). 2020-10-27. 
  17. "China, Europe and the Great Divergence: A Study in Historical National Accounting, 980-1850" (in en-GB). 
  18. Hobbes, Thomas; Malcolm, Noel; Hobbes, Thomas (2014). Leviathan. The Clarendon edition of the works of Thomas Hobbes. Oxford: Clarendon Press. ISBN 978-0-19-870908-4. OCLC 714086778. 
  19. 19.0 19.1 19.2 Galor, Oded (2022). The Journey of humanity: the origins of wealth and inequality. United States: Dutton. ISBN 978-0-593-18599-5. 
  20. Goldstone, Jack Andrew (2002). "Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: Rethinking the "rise of the west" and the industrial revolution" (in English). 
  21. "Globalisation 1.0 and 2.0 helped the G7. Globalisation 3.0 helped India and China instead. What will Globalisation 4.0 do?" (in en). 2019-01-21. 
  22. 22.0 22.1 22.2 22.3 Koyama, Mark; Rubin, Jared T. (2022). How the world became rich: the historical origins of economic growth. Cambridge, UK ; Medford, MA: Polity Press. ISBN 978-1-5095-4023-5. OCLC on1259584967. 
  23. bottom 50
  24. Pinkovskiy, Maxim; Sala-i-Martin, Xavier; Chatterji-Len, Kasey; Nober, William H. (2024-03). "Inequality Within Countries is Falling: Underreporting-Robust Estimates of World Poverty, Inequality and the Global Distribution of Income" (Working Paper). Working Paper Series. doiWikipedia:10.3386/w32203. 
  25. Milanovic, Branko (2023-06-14). "The Great Convergence" (in en-US). Foreign Affairs 102 (4). ISSN 0015-7120. 
  26. "25 Countries Halved Multidimensional Poverty Within 15 Years, but 1.1 Billion Remain Poor" (in en). 
  27. Grinin, Leonid; Korotaev, Andrej Vitalʹevič; Goldstone, Jack A. (2015). Great divergence and great convergence: a global perspective. International perspectives on social policy, administration, and practice. Cham Heidelberg: Springer. ISBN 978-3-319-17779-3. 
  28. Mahbubani, Kishore (2013). The great convergence: Asia, the West, and the logic of one world (First edition ed.). New York: PublicAffairs. ISBN 978-1-61039-033-0. 
  29. Baldwin, Richard E. (2016). The great convergence: information technology and the new globalization. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-66048-9. 
  30. "In the grip of a great convergence". 
  31. "UNU WIDER : Press release: Progress on poverty reduction falling short of Global Goals – New projections predict extreme poverty on the rise in low-income countries" (in en). 2023-10-17. 
  32. Ahmed, Kaamil (2023-03-13). "Extreme poverty could be eradicated globally by 2050 – report" (in en-GB). The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. 
  33. Lucas,, Robert E. Jr. On the Mechanics of Economic Development (1987). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 61–70. ISBN 978-1-139-05217-7. Retrieved 2024-10-06. 
  34. Morris, Ian (2011). Why the West rules - for now: the patterns of history and what they reveal about the future. London: Profile Books. ISBN 978-1-84668-208-7. 
  35. Henrich, Joseph Patrick (2016). The secret of our success: how culture is driving human evolution, domesticating our species, and making us smarter. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-16685-8. OCLC 908084074. 
  36. Richerson, Peter J.; Boyd, Robert (2010-12-31). Six. The Evolution of Free Enterprise Values. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 107–141. Retrieved 2024-10-06. 
  37. Kong, Qiu; Watson, Burton (2010). The analects of Confucius. Translations from the Asian classics. New York: Columbia Univ. Press. ISBN 978-0-231-14165-9. 
  38. North, Douglass C. (1991-03). "Institutions" (in en). Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97–112. doiWikipedia:10.1257/jep.5.1.97. ISSN 0895-3309. 
  39. See the Wikipedia article on List of countries by GDP (PPP) per capita.
  40. See the Wikipedia article on List of countries by life expectancy.
  41. Acemoglu, Daron; Naidu, Suresh; Restrepo, Pascual; Robinson, James A. (2019-02). "Democracy Does Cause Growth" (in en). Journal of Political Economy 127 (1): 47–100. doiWikipedia:10.1086/700936. ISSN 0022-3808. 
  42. 42.0 42.1 42.2 42.3 Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James (2012). "The Making of Prosperity and Property". Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity and poverty ([CA & US version] ed.). New York. ISBN 978-1-84765-461-8. OCLC 785572565. 
  43. 43.0 43.1 Roberts, J. M.; Westad, Odd Arne; Roberts, J. M. (2013). The history of the world (Sixth edition ed.). Oxford ; New York, NY: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-993676-2. 
  44. See the Wikipedia article on Japanese colonial empire.
  45. Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; no text was provided for refs named galor
  46. Hayek, Friedrich A. (1969). Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. Touchstone. ISBN 978-0671202460. 
  47. "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974" (in en-US). 
  48. Beard, Mary (2015). S.P.Q.R: A History of Ancient Rome (Illustrated ed.). Liveright Publishing Corporation. ISBN 978-0871404237. 
  49. Atiyah, P. S. (1985). The rise and fall of freedom of contract. Oxford [Oxfordshire] : New York: Clarendon Press ; Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-825527-7. 
  50. Acemoglu, Daron; Wolitzky (2009-12). "The Economics of Labor Coercion" (Working Paper). Working Paper Series. doiWikipedia:10.3386/w15581. 
  51. Bigoni, Maria; Bortolotti, Stefania; Casari, Marco; Gambetta, Diego; Pancotto, Francesca (2016-08). "Amoral Familism, Social Capital, or Trust? The Behavioural Foundations of the Italian North-South Divide" (in en). The Economic Journal 126 (594): 1318–1341. doiWikipedia:10.1111/ecoj.12292. 
  52. "The origins of the gap between Northern and Southern Italy - Bocconi University" (in en). 2021-09-28. 
  53. "China’s data ‘black box’ puzzles economists | Financial Times". 2023-09-27. 
  54. "China’s Official Economic Data: Is It Accurate? | St. Louis Fed" (in en). 
  55. "China’s Economic Growth Comes in Worse Than Expected, Adding Pressure on Xi" (in en). Bloomberg.com. 2024-07-15. 

Licensed under CC BY-SA 3.0 | Source: https://rationalwiki.org/wiki/Poverty
22 views | Status: cached on November 08 2024 22:03:09
↧ Download this article as ZWI file
Encyclosphere.org EncycloReader is supported by the EncyclosphereKSF