Table of Contents Categories
  Encyclosphere.org ENCYCLOREADER
  supported by EncyclosphereKSF

Economics of climate change mitigation

From Wikipedia - Reading time: 54 min

Companies, governments and households have committed increasing amounts to decarbonization, including renewable energy (solar, wind), electric vehicles and associated charging infrastructure, energy storage, energy-efficient heating systems, carbon capture and storage, and hydrogen.[1][2][3]

The economics of climate change mitigation is a contentious part of climate change mitigation – action aimed to limit the dangerous socio-economic and environmental consequences of climate change.[4]

Climate change mitigation centres on two main strategies: the reduction of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and the preservation and expansion of sinks which absorb greenhouse gases, including the sea and forests.

The economics of climate change mitigation are a central point of contention whose considerations significantly affect the level of climate action at every level from local to global.

For example, higher interest rates are slowing solar panel installation in developing countries.[5]

Public good issues

[edit]

The atmosphere is an international public good and GHG emissions are an international externality.[6] A change in the quality of the atmosphere does not affect the welfare of all individuals and countries equally.

Heterogeneity

[edit]

GHG emissions are unevenly distributed around the world, as are the potential impacts of climate change. Nations with higher than average emissions that face potentially small negative/positive climate change impacts have little incentive to reduce their emissions. Nations that avoid mitigation can benefit from free-riding on the actions of others, and may even enjoy gains in trade and/or investment.[7][obsolete source] The unequal distribution of benefits from mitigation, and the potential advantages of free-riding, made it difficult to secure the Paris Agreement,[citation needed] which aims to reduce emissions.

Intergenerational transfers

[edit]

Mitigation of climate change can be considered a transfer of wealth from the present generation to future generations.[8] The amount of mitigation determines the composition of resources (e.g., environmental or material) that future generations receive. Across generations, the costs and benefits of mitigation are not equally shared: future generations potentially benefit from mitigation, while the present generation bear the costs of mitigation but do not directly benefit[9] (ignoring possible co-benefits,[why?] such as reduced air pollution). If the current generation also benefitted from mitigation, it might lead them to be more willing to bear the costs of mitigation.

Policies and approaches to reduce emissions

[edit]

Price signals

[edit]

Carbon pricing

[edit]

A carbon price is a system of applying a price to carbon emissions, as a method of emissions mitigation.[10] Potential methods of pricing include carbon emission trading, results-based climate finance, crediting mechanisms and more.[11] Carbon pricing can lend itself to the creation of carbon taxes, which allows governments to tax emissions.[10]

Carbon tax
[edit]

Carbon taxes are considered useful because, once a number[clarification needed] has been created, it will benefit the government either with currency or with a lowering in emissions or both, and therefore benefit the environment.[12] It is almost a consensus that carbon taxing is the most cost-effective method of having a substantial and rapid response to climate change and carbon emissions.[13] However, backlash to the tax includes that it can be considered regressive, as the impact can be damaging disproportionately to the poor who spend much of their income on energy for their homes.[14] Still, even with near universal approval, there are issues regarding both the collection and redistribution of the taxes. One of the central questions being how the newly collected taxes will be redistributed.[15]

Some or all of the proceeds of a carbon tax can be used to stop it disadvantaging the poor.[16]

Structural market reforms

[edit]

Market-orientated reforms, as undertaken by several countries in the 1990s, can have important effects on energy use, energy efficiency, and therefore GHG emissions. In a literature assessment, Bashmakov et al. (2001:409) gave the example of China, which has made structural reforms with the aim of increasing GDP.[17] They found that since 1978, energy use in China had increased by an average of 4% per year, but at the same time, energy use had been reduced per unit of GDP.

Emissions trading

[edit]

In addition to the implementation of command-and-control regulations (as with a carbon tax), governments can also use market-based approaches to mitigate emissions. One such method is emissions trading where governments set the total emissions of all polluters to a maximum and distribute permits, through auction or allocation, that allow entities to emit a portion, typically one ton of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e), of the mandated total emissions.[18] In other words, the amount of pollution an entity can emit in an emissions trading system is limited by the number of permits they have. If a polluter wants to increase their emissions, they can only do so after buying permits from those who are willing to sell them.[19] Many economists prefer this method of reducing emissions as it is market based and highly cost effective.[18] That being said, emissions trading alone is not perfect since it fails to place a clear price on emissions. Without this price, emissions prices are volatile due to the supply of permits being fixed, meaning their price is entirely determined by shifts in demand.[20] This uncertainty in price is especially disliked by businesses since it prevents them from investing in abatement technologies with confidence which hinders efforts for mitigating emissions.[20] Regardless, while emissions trading alone has its problems and cannot reduce pollutants to the point of stabilizing the global climate, it remains an important tool for addressing climate change.

Degrowth

[edit]

There is a debate about a potentially critical need for new ways of economic accounting, including directly monitoring and quantifying positive real-world environmental effects such as air quality improvements and related unprofitable work like forest protection, alongside far-reaching structural changes of lifestyles[21][22] as well as acknowledging and moving beyond the limits of current economics such as GDP.[23] Some argue that for effective climate change mitigation degrowth has to occur, while some argue that eco-economic decoupling could limit climate change enough while continuing high rates of traditional GDP growth.[24][25] There is also research and debate about requirements of how economic systems could be transformed for sustainability – such as how their jobs could transition harmonously into green jobs – a just transition – and how relevant sectors of the economy – like the renewable energy industry and the bioeconomy – could be adequately supported.[26][27]

While degrowth is often believed to be associated with decreased living standards and austerity measures, many of its proponents seek to expand universal public goods[28][29] (such as public transport), increase health[30][31][32] (fitness, wellbeing[33] and freedom from diseases) and increase various forms of, often unconventional commons-oriented,[34] labor. To this end, the application of both advanced technologies and reductions in various demands, including via overall reduced labor time[35] or sufficiency-oriented strategies,[36] are considered to be important by some.[37][38]

Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies

[edit]

Significant fossil fuel subsidies are present in many countries.[39] Fossil fuel subsidies in 2019 for consumption totalled US$320 billion[40] spread over many countries.[41] As of 2019 governments subsidise fossil fuels by about $500 billion per year: however using an unconventional definition of subsidy which includes failing to price greenhouse gas emissions, the International Monetary Fund estimated that fossil fuel subsidies were $5.2 trillion in 2017, which was 6.4% of global GDP.[42] Some fossil fuel companies lobby governments.[43]

Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies is crucial to address the climate crisis.[44] It must however be done carefully to avoid protests[45] and making poor people poorer.[46] In most cases, however, low fossil fuel prices benefit wealthier households more than poorer households. So to help poor and vulnerable people, other measures than fossil fuel subsidies would be more targeted.[47] This could in turn increase public support for subsidy reform.[48]

Economic theory indicates that the optimal policy would be to remove coal mining and burning subsidies and replace them with optimal[clarification needed] taxes. Global studies indicate that even without introducing taxes, subsidy and trade barrier removal at a sectoral level would improve efficiency and reduce environmental damage.[49] Removal of these subsidies would substantially reduce greenhouse gas emissions and create jobs in renewable energy.[50] The IMF estimated in 2023 that removal of fossil fuel subsidies would limit global heating to the Paris goal of substantially less than 2 °C.[51]

Policies

[edit]

National policies

[edit]

International policies

[edit]

Paris Agreement

[edit]

The Paris Agreement (also called the Paris Accords or Paris Climate Accords) is an international treaty on climate change that was signed in 2016.[52] The treaty covers climate change mitigation, adaptation, and finance. The Paris Agreement was negotiated by 196 parties at the 2015 United Nations Climate Change Conference near Paris, France. As of February 2023, 195 members of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) are parties to the agreement. Of the three UNFCCC member states which have not ratified the agreement, the only major emitter is Iran. The United States withdrew from the agreement in 2020,[53] but rejoined in 2021.[54]

The Paris Agreement has a long-term temperature goal which is to keep the rise in global surface temperature to well below 2 °C (3.6 °F) above pre-industrial levels. The treaty also states that preferably the limit of the increase should only be 1.5 °C (2.7 °F). The lower the temperature increase, the smaller the effects of climate change can be expected. To achieve this temperature goal, greenhouse gas emissions should be reduced as soon as, and by as much as, possible. They should even reach net zero by the middle of the 21st century.[55] To stay below 1.5 °C of global warming, emissions need to be cut by roughly 50% by 2030. This figure takes into account each country's documented pledges.[56]

The treaty aims to help countries adapt to climate change effects, and mobilize enough finance. Under the agreement, each country must determine, plan, and regularly report on its contributions. No mechanism forces a country to set specific emissions targets, but each target should go beyond previous targets. In contrast to the 1997 Kyoto Protocol, the distinction between developed and developing countries is blurred, so that the latter also have to submit plans for emission reductions.

Other policies

[edit]
  • Regulatory instruments: This could involve the setting of regulatory standards for various products and processes for countries to adopt. The other option is to set national emission limits. The second option leads to inefficiency because the marginal costs of abatement differs between countries.[17]: 430 

Initiatives such as the EU "cap and trade" system have also been implemented.[57]

  • Carbon taxes: This would offer a potentially cost-effective means of reducing CO2 emissions. Compared with emissions trading, international or harmonized (where each country keeps the revenue it collects) taxes provide greater certainty about the likely costs of emission reductions. This is also true of a hybrid policy (see carbon tax).[17]: 430 

Efficiency of international agreements

[edit]

For the purposes of analysis, it is possible to separate efficiency from equity.[6]: 30  It has been suggested that because of the low energy efficiency in many developing countries, efforts should first be made in those countries to reduce emissions.[clarification needed] There are a number of policies to improve efficiency, including:[6]: 34 

  • Property rights reform. For example, deforestation could be reduced through reform of property rights.
  • Administrative reforms. For example, in many countries, electricity is priced at the cost of production. Economists, however, recommend that electricity, like any other good, should be priced at the competitive price.[citation needed]
  • Regulating non-greenhouse externalities. There are externalities other than the emission of GHGs, for example, road congestion leading to air pollution. Addressing these externalities, e.g., through congestion pricing and energy taxes, could help to lower both air pollution and GHG emissions.

General equilibrium theory

One of the aspects of efficiency for an international agreement on reducing emissions is participation. In order to be efficient, mechanisms to reduce emissions still require all emitters to face the same costs of emission.[6]: 30  Partial participation significantly reduces the effectiveness of policies to reduce emissions. This is because of how the global economy is connected through trade.

General equilibrium theory points to a number of difficulties with partial participation. Examples are of "leakage" (carbon leakage) of emissions from countries with regulations on GHG emissions to countries with less regulation. For example, stringent regulation in developed countries could result in polluting industries such as aluminium production moving production to developing countries. Leakage is a type of "spillover" effect of mitigation policies.

Estimates of spillover effects are uncertain.[58] If mitigation policies are only implemented in Kyoto Annex I countries, some researchers have concluded that spillover effects might render these policies ineffective, or possibly even cause global emissions to increase.[59] Others have suggested that spillover might be beneficial and result in reduced emission intensities in developing countries.

Comprehensiveness

Efficiency also requires that the costs of emission reductions be minimized.[6]: 31  This implies that all GHGs (CO2, methane, etc.) are considered as part of a policy to reduce emissions, and also that carbon sinks are included. Perhaps most controversially, the requirement for efficiency implies that all parts of the Kaya identity are included as part of a mitigation policy.[60] The components of the Kaya identity are:

  • CO2 emissions per unit of energy, (carbon intensity)
  • energy per unit of output, (energy efficiency)
  • economic output per capita,
  • and human population.

Efficiency requires that the marginal costs of mitigation for each of these components is equal. In other words, from the perspective of improving the overall efficiency of a long-term mitigation strategy, population control has as much "validity" as efforts made to improve energy efficiency.

Equity in international agreements

[edit]

Unlike efficiency, there is no consensus view of how to assess the fairness of a particular climate policy (Bashmakov et al., 2001:438–439;[17] see also economics of global warming#Paying for an international public good). This does not prevent the study of how a particular policy impacts welfare. Edmonds et al. (1995) estimated that a policy of stabilizing national emissions without trading would, by 2020, shift more than 80% of the aggregate policy costs to non-OECD regions (Bashmakov et al., 2001:439). A common global carbon tax would result in an uneven burden of abatement costs across the world and would change with time. With a global tradable quota system, welfare impacts would vary according to quota allocation.

Finance

[edit]
Bloomberg NEF reported that in 2022, global energy transition investment equaled fossil fuels investment for the first time.[61]
Clean energy investment has benefited from post-pandemic economic recovery, a global energy crisis involving high fossil fuel prices, and growing policy support across various nations.[62]

Article 4.2 of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change commits industrialized countries to "[take] the lead" in reducing emissions.[63] The Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC has provided only limited financial support to developing countries to assist them in climate change mitigation and adaptation.[64]: 233  Additionally, private sector investment in mitigation and adaptation was predicted to be discouraged because of the Great Recession.[65]: xix 

The International Energy Agency estimates that US$197 billion is required by states in the developing world above and beyond the underlying investments needed by various sectors regardless of climate considerations, this is twice the amount promised by the developed world at the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Cancún Agreements.[66] Thus, a new method is being developed to help ensure that funding is available for climate change mitigation.[66] This involves financial leveraging, whereby public financing is used to encourage private investment.[66]

The private sector is often unwilling to finance low carbon technologies in developing and emerging economies as the market incentives are often lacking.[66] There are many perceived risks involved, in particular:[66]

  1. General political risk associated politically instability, uncertain property rights and an unfamiliar legal framework.[66]
  2. Currency risks are involved is financing is sought internationally and not provided in the nationally currency.[66]
  3. Regulatory and policy risk – if the public incentives provided by a state may not be actually provided, or if provided, then not for the full length of the investment.[66]
  4. Execution risk – reflecting concern that the local project developer/firm may lack the capacity and/or experience to execute the project efficiently.[66]
  5. Technology risk as new technologies involved in low carbon technology may not work as well as expected.[66]
  6. Unfamiliarity risks occur when investors have never undertaken such projects before.[66]

Funds from the developed world can help mitigate these risks and thus leverage much larger private funds, the current aim to create $3 of private investment for every $1 of public funds.[67]: 4  Public funds can be used to minimise the risks in the following way.[66]

  • Loan guarantees provided by international public financial institutions can be useful to reduce the risk to private lenders.[66]
  • Policy insurance can insurance the investor against changes or disruption to government policies designed to encourage low carbon technology, such as a feed-in tariff.[66]
  • Foreign exchange liquidity facilities can help reduce the risks associated with borrowing money in a different currency by creating a line of credit that can be drawn on when the project needs money as a result of local currency devaluation but then repaid when the project has a financial surplus.[66]
  • Pledge fund can help projects are too small for equity investors to consider or unable to access sufficient equity. In this model, public finance sponsors provide a small amount of equity to anchor and encourage much larger pledges from private investors, such as sovereign wealth funds, large private equity firms and pension funds. Private equity investors will tend to be risk-averse and focused primarily on long-term profitability, thus all projects would need to meet the fiduciary requirements of the investors.[66]
  • Subordinated equity fund – an alternative use of public finance is through the provision of subordinated equity, meaning that the repayment on the equity is of lower priority than the repayment of other equity investors.[66] The subordinated equity would aim to leverage other equity investors by ensuring that the latter have first claim on the distribution of profit, thereby increasing their risk-adjusted returns.[66] The fund would have claim on profits only after rewards to other equity investors were distributed.[66]
More firms (in Europe) plan to invest in low-carbon sectors, and to tackle climate change.[68]

An investment survey conducted by the European Investment Bank in 2021 found that during the COVID-19 pandemic, climate change was addressed by 43% of EU enterprises. Despite the pandemic's effect on businesses, the percentage of firms planning climate-related investment rose to 47%. In 2020, the percentage of climate related investment was at 41%.[68]

62% of Europeans believe that the green transition will reduce their buying power.[69]

Eastern European and Central Asian businesses fall behind their Southern European counterparts in terms of the average quality of their green management practices, notably in terms of specified energy consumption and emissions objectives.[70][71] External variables, such as consumer pressure and energy taxes, are more relevant than firm-level features, such as size and age, in influencing the quality of green management practices. Firms with less financial limitations and stronger green management practices are more likely to invest in a bigger variety of green initiatives. Energy efficiency investments are good to both the bottom line and the environment.[70][71]

In 2023 almost 7 trillion dollars were invested in nature damaging activities if count only the direct impacts. Large part of it is money going to fossil fuels. 200 billion was invested in nature based solutions.[72]

Europe

[edit]

The European Investment Bank plans to support €1 trillion of climate investment by 2030 as part of the European Green Deal.[73] In 2019 the EIB Board of Directors approved new targets for climate action and environmental sustainability to phase out fossil fuel financing.[74][75] The bank will increase the share of its financing for to climate action and environmental sustainability to 50% by 2025 The European Investment Bank Group announced it will align all financing with the Paris Agreement by the end of 2020. The bank aims "to play a leading role in mobilising the finance needed to achieve the worldwide commitment to keep global warming well below 2˚C, aiming for 1.5˚C."[76][77] EIB loans to the sustainable blue economy totalled €6.7 billion between 2018 and 2022, generating €23.8 billion in investments, and €2.8 billion in maritime renewable energy.[78] In the same timeframe, the Bank granted around €881 million to assist in the management of wastewater, stormwater, and solid waste to decrease pollution entering the ocean.[79][80] In 2023, EIB energy loans climbed to €21.3 billion, up from €11.6 billion in 2020. This funding supports energy efficiency, renewable energy, innovation, storage, and new energy network infrastructure.[81]

The EIB, the European Commission, and Breakthrough Energy, launched by Bill Gates in 2015, have collaborated to build large-scale green tech initiatives in Europe and encourage investment in crucial climate technologies.[82]

A survey in 2020 found that 45% of EU companies have invested in climate change mitigation or adaptation measures, compared to 32% in the US. Fewer companies plan future investment in the years following the COVID-19 pandemic. 40% of European companies want to invest in climate initiatives during the next three years. The proportion of investment in 2020 varies from 50% in Western and Northern Europe to 32% in Central and Eastern Europe. The majority of European companies, 75%, say regulatory and tax uncertainty is preventing them from investing in climate-related projects.[83][84][85]

According to a 2020 Municipality Survey, 56% of European Union municipalities increased climate investment, while 66% believe their climate investment over the previous three years has been insufficient.[86][87][83] In the three years preceding the pandemic, over two-thirds of EU towns boosted infrastructure investments, with a 56% focus on climate change mitigation.[88]

Local municipalities contribute 45% of total government investment. Basic infrastructure, such as public transportation or water utilities, is included in their investment. They also update public facilities including schools, hospitals, and social housing. Prioritizing energy efficiency in these projects will assist Europe in meeting climate targets.[89][88]

Municipal investment began to increase again about 2017. In the three years preceding the pandemic, over two-thirds of EU towns boosted infrastructure investments. This investment has tended to concentrate on certain types of infrastructure, such as digital infrastructure, at 70% of municipalities and social services at 60%, as well as climate change mitigation at 56%.[88] Cities and towns are also responsible for around 70% of total greenhouse gas emissions.[88]

Assessing costs and benefits

[edit]

GDP

[edit]

The costs of mitigation and adaptation policies can be measured as a percentage of GDP. A problem with this method of assessing costs is that GDP is an imperfect measure of welfare.[90]: 478  There are externalities in the economy which mean that some prices might not be truly reflective of their social costs.

Corrections can be made to GDP estimates to allow for these problems, but they are difficult to calculate. In response to this problem, some have suggested using other methods to assess policy. For example, the United Nations Commission for Sustainable Development has developed a system for "Green" GDP accounting and a list of sustainable development indicators.

Baselines

[edit]

The emissions baseline is, by definition, the emissions that would occur in the absence of policy intervention. Definition of the baseline scenario is critical in the assessment of mitigation costs.[90]: 469  This because the baseline determines the potential for emissions reductions, and the costs of implementing emission reduction policies.

There are several concepts used in the literature over baselines, including the "efficient" and "business-as-usual" (BAU) baseline cases. In the efficient baseline, it is assumed that all resources are being employed efficiently. In the BAU case, it is assumed that future development trends follow those of the past, and no changes in policies will take place. The BAU baseline is often associated with high GHG emissions, and may reflect the continuation of current energy-subsidy policies, or other market failures.

Some high emission BAU baselines imply relatively low net mitigation costs per unit of emissions. If the BAU scenario projects a large growth in emissions, total mitigation costs can be relatively high. Conversely, in an efficient baseline, mitigation costs per unit of emissions can be relatively high, but total mitigation costs low.[clarification needed]

Ancillary impacts

[edit]

These are the secondary or side effects of mitigation policies, and including them in studies can result in higher or lower mitigation cost estimates.[90]: 455  Reduced mortality and morbidity costs are potentially a major ancillary benefit of mitigation. This benefit is associated with reduced use of fossil fuels, thereby resulting in less air pollution, which might even just by itself be a benefit greater than the cost.[91]: 48  There may also be ancillary costs.

Flexibility

[edit]

Flexibility is the ability to reduce emissions at the lowest cost. The greater the flexibility that governments allow in their regulatory framework to reduce emissions, the lower the potential costs are for achieving emissions reductions (Markandya et al., 2001:455).[90]

  • "Where" flexibility allows costs to be reduced by allowing emissions to be cut at locations where it is most efficient to do so. For example, the Flexibility Mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol allow "where" flexibility (Toth et al., 2001:660).[8]
  • "When" flexibility potentially lowers costs by allowing reductions to be made at a time when it is most efficient to do so.

Including carbon sinks in a policy framework is another source of flexibility. Tree planting and forestry management actions can increase the capacity of sinks. Soils and other types of vegetation are also potential sinks. There is, however, uncertainty over how net emissions are affected by activities in this area.[90][clarification needed]

No regrets options

[edit]

No regret options are social and economic benefits developed under the assumption of taking action and establishing preventative measures in current times without fully knowing what climate change will look like in the future.[92][93]

These are emission reduction options which can also make a lot of profit – such as adding solar and wind power.[94]: TS-108 

Different studies make different assumptions about how far the economy is from the production frontier (defined as the maximum outputs attainable with the optimal use of available inputs – natural resources, labour, etc.).[95]

The benefits of coal phase out exceed the costs.[96] Switching from cars by improving walking and cycling infrastructure is either free or beneficial to a country's economy as a whole.[97]

Technology

[edit]

Assumptions about technological development and efficiency in the baseline and mitigation scenarios have a major impact on mitigation costs, in particular in bottom-up studies.[90] The magnitude of potential technological efficiency improvements depends on assumptions about future technological innovation and market penetration rates for these technologies.

Discount rates

[edit]

Assessing climate change impacts and mitigation policies involves a comparison of economic flows that occur in different points in time. The discount rate is used by economists to compare economic effects occurring at different times. Discounting converts future economic impacts into their present-day value. The discount rate is generally positive because resources invested today can, on average, be transformed into more resources later. If climate change mitigation is viewed as an investment, then the return on investment can be used to decide how much should be spent on mitigation.

Integrated assessment models (IAM) are used to estimate the social cost of carbon. The discount rate is one of the factors used in these models. The IAM frequently used is the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy (DICE) model developed by William Nordhaus. The DICE model uses discount rates, uncertainty, and risks to make benefit and cost estimations of climate policies and adapt to the current economic behavior.[98]

The choice of discount rate has a large effect on the result of any climate change cost analysis (Halsnæs et al., 2007:136).[7] Using too high a discount rate will result in too little investment in mitigation, but using too low a rate will result in too much investment in mitigation. In other words, a high discount rate implies that the present-value of a dollar is worth more than the future-value of a dollar.

Discounting can either be prescriptive or descriptive. The descriptive approach is based on what discount rates are observed in the behaviour of people making every day decisions (the private discount rate) (IPCC, 2007c:813).[95] In the prescriptive approach, a discount rate is chosen based on what is thought to be in the best interests of future generations (the social discount rate).

The descriptive approach can be interpreted[clarification needed] as an effort to maximize the economic resources available to future generations, allowing them to decide how to use those resources (Arrow et al., 1996b:133–134).[99] The prescriptive approach can be interpreted as an effort to do as much as is economically justified[clarification needed] to reduce the risk of climate change.

The DICE model incorporates a descriptive approach, in which discounting reflects actual economic conditions. In a recent[when?] DICE model, DICE-2013R Model, the social cost of carbon is estimated based on the following alternative scenarios: (1) a baseline scenario, when climate change policies have not changed since 2010, (2) an optimal scenario, when climate change policies are optimal (fully implemented and followed), (3) when the optimal scenario does not exceed 2˚C limit after 1900 data, (4) when the 2˚C limit is an average and not the optimum, (5) when a near-zero (low) discount rate of 0.1% is used (as assumed in the Stern Review), (6) when a near-zero discount rate is also used but with calibrated interest rates, and (7) when a high discount rate of 3.5% is used.[100][needs update]

According to Markandya et al. (2001:466), discount rates used in assessing mitigation programmes need to at least partly reflect the opportunity costs of capital.[90] In developed countries, Markandya et al. (2001:466) thought that a discount rate of around 4–6% was probably justified, while in developing countries, a rate of 10–12% was cited. The discount rates used in assessing private projects were found to be higher – with potential rates of between 10% and 25%.

When deciding how to discount future climate change impacts, value judgements are necessary (Arrow et al., 1996b:130). IPCC (2001a:9) found that there was no consensus on the use of long-term discount rates in this area.[101] The prescriptive approach to discounting leads to long-term discount rates of 2–3% in real terms, while the descriptive approach leads to rates of at least 4% after tax – sometimes much higher (Halsnæs et al., 2007:136).

Even today, it is difficult to agree on an appropriate discount rate. The approach of discounting to be either prescriptive or descriptive stemmed from the views of Nordhaus and Stern. Nordhaus takes on a descriptive approach which "assumes that investments to slow climate change must compete with investments in other areas". While Stern takes on a prescriptive approach in which "leads to the conclusion that any positive pure rate of time preference is unethical".[98]

In Nordhaus' view, his descriptive approach translates that the impact of climate change is slow, thus investments in climate change should be on the same level of competition with other investments. He defines the discount rate to be the rate of return on capital investments. The DICE model uses the estimated market return on capital as the discount rate, around an average of 4%. He argues that a higher discount rate will make future damages look small, thus have less effort to reduce emissions today. A lower discount rate will make future damages look larger, thus put more effort to reduce emissions today.[102]

In Stern's view, the pure rate of time preference is defined as the discount rate in a scenario where present and future generations have equal resources and opportunities.[103] A zero pure rate of time preference in this case would indicate that all generations are treated equally. The future generation do not have a "voice" on today's current policies, so the present generation are morally responsible to treat the future generation in the same manner. He suggests for a lower discount rate in which the present generation should invest in the future to reduce the risks of climate change.

Assumptions are made to support estimating high and low discount rates. These estimates depend on future emissions, climate sensitivity relative to increase in greenhouse gas concentrations, and the seriousness of impacts over time.[104] Long-term climate policies will significantly impact future generations and this is called intergenerational discounting. Factors that make intergenerational discounting complicated include the great uncertainty of economic growth, future generations are affected by today's policies, and private discounting will be affected due to a longer "investment horizon".[105]

Controversy

[edit]

Discounting is a relatively controversial issue in both climate change mitigation and environmental economics due to the ethical implications of valuing future generations less than present ones. Non-economists often find it difficult to grapple with the idea that thousands of dollars of future costs and benefits can be valued at less than a cent in the present after discounting.[106] This devaluation can lead to overconsumption and "strategic ignorance" where individuals choose to ignore information that would prevent the overconsumption of resources.[107] Contrary to this, orthodox economists concerned with equality argue that it is important to distribute society's resources equitably across time, and since they generally, rightly or wrongly predict positive economic growth, despite global climate change, they argue that current generations should damage the environment in which future generations live so that the current ones can consume and produce more to equalize the (rightly or wrongly) assumed gains to the future from a supposed growing net GDP.[108] That being said, not all economists share this opinion as notable economist Frank Ramsey once described discounting as "ethically indefensible."[108]

One root of this controversy can be attributed to the discrepancies between the time scales environmentalists and corporations/governments view the world with. Environmental processes such as the carbonate-silicate cycle and Milankovitch cycles occur on timescales of thousands of years while economic processes, such as infrastructure investments, occur on time scales as short as thirty years. The difference between these two scales makes balancing both interests, sustainability and efficiency, incredibly difficult.[108]

Implementation

[edit]

Because discounting rates are determined and implemented by individual governments, discounting rates are not unanimous across the globe.[109] They range from percentages as high as 15%, as in the Philippines, to as low as 3%, as in Germany.[109]

United States
[edit]

Discounting in the United States is a complicated area for policy analysis. The discounting rate is not the same for every government agency. As of 1992, the recommended discounting rate from the Environmental Protection Agency is 2–3% while the Office of Management and Budget recommends a discount rate of 7%.[110][109] Further complicating things, these rates are fluid and change every year depending on the administration.[111]

United Kingdom
[edit]

The United Kingdom is one of very few[citation needed] governmental bodies that currently use what is known as a declining discount rate.[112] Declining discount rates are gaining popularity due to the fact that they address the uncertainties in economic growth which allows for greater weight to be placed on future benefits, but the extent to this advantage remains to be proven.[113][114]

Decision analysis

[edit]

This is a quantitative type of analysis that is used to assess different potential decisions. Examples are cost-benefit and cost-effectiveness analysis.[8] In cost-benefit analysis, both costs and benefits are assessed economically. In cost-effectiveness analysis, the benefit-side of the analysis, e.g., a specified ceiling for the atmospheric concentration of GHGs, is not based on economic assessment.

One of the benefits of decision analysis is that the analysis is reproducible. Weaknesses, however, have been citied:[115]

  • The decision maker:
    • In decision analysis, it is assumed that a single decision maker, with well-order preferences, is present throughout the analysis. In a cost-benefit analysis, the preferences of the decision maker are determined by applying the concepts of "willingness to pay" (WTP) and "willingness to accept" (WTA). These concepts are applied in an attempt to determine the aggregate value that society places on different resources.[90]
    • In reality, there is no single decision maker. Different decision makers have different sets of values and preferences, and for this reason, decision analysis cannot yield a universally preferred solution.
  • Utility valuation: Many of the outcomes of climate policy decisions are difficult to value.

Arrow et al. (1996a) concluded that while decision analysis had value, it could not identify a globally optimal policy for mitigation. In determining nationally optimal mitigation policies, the problems of decision analysis were viewed as being less important.

Cost-benefit analysis

[edit]

In an economically efficient mitigation response, the marginal (or incremental) costs of mitigation would be balanced against the marginal benefits[to whom?] of emission reduction. "Marginal" means that the costs and benefits of preventing (abating) the emission of the last unit of CO2-eq are being compared. Units are measured in tonnes of CO2-eq. The marginal benefits are the avoided damages from an additional tonne of carbon (emitted as carbon dioxide) being abated in a given emissions pathway (the social cost of carbon).

A problem with this approach is that the marginal costs and benefits of mitigation are uncertain, particularly with regards to the benefits of mitigation (Munasinghe et al., 1996, p. 159).[116] In the absence of risk aversion, and certainty over the costs and benefits, the optimum level of mitigation would be the point where marginal costs equal marginal benefits. As of 2022 the models are not good enough to be certain, but the IPCC said that "emerging evidence suggests that, even without accounting for co-benefits of mitigation on other sustainable development dimensions, the global benefits of pathways likely to limit warming to 2°C outweigh global mitigation costs over the 21st century" (see economics of global warming#Trade offs).[117]: 51 

Damage function

In cost-benefit analysis, the optimal timing of mitigation depends more on the shape of the aggregate damage function than the overall damages of climate change (Fisher et al., 2007:235).[4][better source needed] If a damage function is used that shows smooth and regular damages, e.g., a cubic function, the results suggest that emission abatement should be postponed. This is because the benefits of early abatement are outweighed by the benefits of investing in other areas that accelerate economic growth. This result can change if the damage function is changed to include the possibility of catastrophic climate change impacts.

Cost-effectiveness analysis

[edit]

CEA, like CBA, is a type of decision analysis method. Decision analysis requires a selection criterion to be specified as well as agreement on how "optimal" is defined. In a decision analysis based on monetized cost–benefit analysis (CBA), the optimal policy is evaluated in economic terms. The optimal result of monetized CBA maximizes net benefits. Monetized CBA may be used to decide on the policy objective, e.g., how much emissions should be allowed to grow over time. The benefits of emissions reductions are included as part of the assessment.[118] Unlike in CBA, CEA does not suggest an optimal climate policy. For example, CEA may be used to determine how to stabilize atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations at lowest cost. However, the actual choice of stabilization target (e.g., 450 or 550 ppm carbon dioxide equivalent), is not "decided" in the analysis.

The choice of selection criterion for decision analysis is subjective.[118] The choice of criterion is made outside of the analysis (it is exogenous). One of the influences on this choice on this is attitude to risk. Risk aversion describes how willing or unwilling someone is to take risks. Evidence indicates that most, but not all, individuals[clarification needed] prefer certain outcomes to uncertain ones. Risk-averse individuals prefer decision criteria that reduce the chance of the worst possible outcome, while risk-seeking individuals prefer decision criteria that maximize the chance of the best possible outcome. In terms of returns on investment, if society as a whole is risk-averse, we might be willing to accept some investments with negative expected returns, e.g., in mitigation.[119] Such investments may help to reduce the possibility of future climate damages.

Cost estimates

[edit]

Several factors affect mitigation cost estimates. One is the baseline. This is a reference scenario that the alternative mitigation scenario is compared with. Others are the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[120]: 622  Cost estimates for mitigation for specific regions depend on the quantity of emissions allowed for that region in future, as well as the timing of interventions.[121]: 90 

Mitigation costs will vary according to how and when emissions are cut. Early, well-planned action will minimize the costs.[122] Globally, the benefits of keeping warming under 2 °C exceed the costs.[123]

Economists estimate the cost of climate change mitigation at between 1% and 2% of GDP.[124][125] While this is a large sum, it is still far less than the subsidies governments provide to the ailing fossil fuel industry. The International Monetary Fund estimated this at more than $5 trillion per year.[126][127]

Another estimate says that financial flows for climate mitigation and adaptation are going to be over $800 billion per year. These financial requirements are predicted to exceed $4 trillion per year by 2030.[128][129]

Globally, limiting warming to 2 °C may result in higher economic benefits than economic costs.[130]: 300  The economic repercussions of mitigation vary widely across regions and households, depending on policy design and level of international cooperation. Delayed global cooperation increases policy costs across regions, especially in those that are relatively carbon intensive at present. Pathways with uniform carbon values show higher mitigation costs in more carbon-intensive regions, in fossil-fuels exporting regions and in poorer regions. Aggregate quantifications expressed in GDP or monetary terms undervalue the economic effects on households in poorer countries. The actual effects on welfare and well-being are comparatively larger.[131]

Cost–benefit analysis may be unsuitable for analysing climate change mitigation as a whole. But it is still useful for analysing the difference between a 1.5 °C target and 2 °C.[124] One way of estimating the cost of reducing emissions is by considering the likely costs of potential technological and output changes. Policymakers can compare the marginal abatement costs of different methods to assess the cost and amount of possible abatement over time. The marginal abatement costs of the various measures will differ by country, by sector, and over time.[122]

Eco-tariffs on only imports contribute to reduced global export competitiveness and to deindustrialization.[132]

Global costs

[edit]

Mitigation cost estimates depend critically on the baseline (in this case, a reference scenario that the alternative scenario is compared with), the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[133]: 622  Macroeconomic costs in 2030 were estimated for multi-gas mitigation (reducing emissions of carbon dioxide and other GHGs, such as methane) as between a 3% decrease in global GDP to a small increase, relative to baseline.[4] This was for an emissions pathway consistent with atmospheric stabilization of GHGs between 445 and 710 ppm CO2-eq. In 2050, the estimated costs for stabilization between 710 and 445 ppm CO2-eq ranged between a 1% gain to a 5.5% decrease in global GDP, relative to baseline. These cost estimates were supported by a moderate amount of evidence and much agreement in the literature.[134]: 11, 18 

Macroeconomic cost estimates were mostly based on models that assumed transparent markets, no transaction costs, and perfect implementation of cost-effective policy measures across all regions throughout the 21st century.[4]: 204  Relaxation of some or all these assumptions would lead to an appreciable increase in cost estimates. On the other hand, cost estimates could be reduced by allowing for accelerated technological learning, or the possible use of carbon tax/emission permit revenues to reform national tax systems.[134]: 8 

In most of the assessed studies, costs rose for increasingly stringent stabilization targets. In scenarios that had high baseline emissions, mitigation costs were generally higher for comparable stabilization targets. In scenarios with low emissions baselines, mitigation costs were generally lower for comparable stabilization targets.

Distributional effects

[edit]
The emissions of the richest 1% of the global population account for more than twice the combined share of the poorest 50%. Compliance with the 1.5°C goal of the Paris Agreement would require the richest 1% to reduce their current emissions by at least a factor of 30, while per-person emissions of the poorest 50% could increase by a factor of about three.[135]
This pie chart illustrates both total emissions for each income group, and emissions per person within each income group. For example, the 10% with the highest incomes are responsible for half of carbon emissions, and its members emit an average of more than five times as much per person as members of the lowest half of the income scale.[136]

Regional costs

[edit]

Several studies have estimated regional mitigation costs. The conclusions of these studies are as follows:[137]: 776 

  • Regional abatement costs are largely dependent on the assumed stabilization level and baseline scenario. The allocation of emission allowances/permits is also an important factor, but for most countries, is less important than the stabilization level.
  • Other costs arise from changes in international trade. Fossil fuel-exporting regions are likely to be affected by losses in coal and oil exports compared to baseline, while some regions might experience increased bio-energy (energy derived from biomass) exports.
  • Allocation schemes based on current emissions (i.e., where the most allowances/permits are given to the largest current polluters, and the fewest allowances are given to smallest current polluters) lead to welfare losses for developing countries, while allocation schemes based on a per capita convergence of emissions (i.e., where per capita emissions are equalized) lead to welfare gains for developing countries.

Sectoral costs

[edit]

In 2001 it was predicted that the renewables sector could potentially benefit from mitigation.[138]: 563  The coal (and possibly the oil) industry was predicted to potentially lose substantial proportions of output relative to a baseline scenario.[138]: 563 

Cost sharing

[edit]

Distributing emissions abatement costs

[edit]

There have been different proposals on how to allocate responsibility for cutting emissions:[139]: 103 

  • Egalitarianism: this system interprets the problem as one where each person has equal rights to a global resource, i.e., polluting the atmosphere.
  • Basic needs: this system would have emissions allocated according to basic needs, as defined according to a minimum level of consumption. Consumption above basic needs would require countries to buy more emission rights. From this viewpoint, developing countries would need to be at least as well off under an emissions control regime as they would be outside the regime.
  • Proportionality and polluter-pays principle: Proportionality reflects the ancient Aristotelian principle that people should receive in proportion to what they put in, and pay in proportion to the damages they cause. This has a potential relationship with the "polluter-pays principle", which can be interpreted in a number of ways:
    • Historical responsibilities: this asserts that allocation of emission rights should be based on patterns of past emissions. Two-thirds of the stock of GHGs in the atmosphere at present is due to the past actions of developed countries.[140]: 29 
    • Comparable burdens and ability to pay: with this approach, countries would reduce emissions based on comparable burdens and their ability to take on the costs of reduction. Ways to assess burdens include monetary costs per head of population, as well as other, more complex measures, like the UNDP's Human Development Index.
    • Willingness to pay: with this approach, countries take on emission reductions based on their ability to pay along with how much they benefit[141] from reducing their emissions.

Specific proposals

[edit]
  • Equal per capita entitlements: this is the most widely cited method of distributing abatement costs, and is derived from egalitarianism.[139]: 106  This approach can be divided into two categories. In the first category, emissions are allocated according to national population. In the second category, emissions are allocated in a way that attempts to account for historical (cumulative) emissions.
  • Status quo: with this approach, historical emissions are ignored, and current emission levels are taken as a status quo right to emit.[139]: 107  An analogy for this approach can be made with fisheries, which is a common, limited resource. The analogy would be with the atmosphere, which can be viewed as an exhaustible natural resource.[140]: 27  In international law, one state recognized the long-established use of another state's use of the fisheries resource. It was also recognized by the state that part of the other state's economy was dependent on that resource.

Barriers to change

[edit]

It may not be in the interest of many large companies to help mitigate climate change sufficiently instead of striving to generate near-maximum profit in the current socioeconomic system. The current economic system is operating in a globalized competitive consumption-demanding environment. Companies can use all legal means to delay climate change action if such is beneficial for their profits.[142] Their products are being bought by consumers,[142] and economic components like the stock market underestimate or cannot value social benefits of climate change mitigation[143] – climate change is largely an externality,[144][145][146] despite a limited recent internalization of impacts that previously were fully 'external' to the economy.[147]

Companies are regulatable by governments,[148] and usually aren't as powerful as states or groups of states. States for example can leverage their capacities for law enforcement, customs, legal frameworks, and economic policies. Consumers can be and are affected by policies that relate to e.g. ethical consumer literacy,[149] the available choices they have, transportation policy,[150] product transparency policies,[151][152][153][154] and larger-order economic policies that for example facilitate large-scale shifts of jobs.[155][156]

Such policies or measures are sometimes unpopular with the population. Therefore, they may be difficult for politicians to enact directly or help facilitate indirectly. The question of the largest responsibility or driver may be about who is holding (or withholding) the power (and capacity) to create and change the systems that cause climate change.[142]

According to a study, "staying within a 1.5 °C carbon budget (50% probability) implies leaving almost 40% of 'developed reserves' of fossil fuels unextracted".[157] Climate policies-induced future lost financial profits from global stranded fossil-fuel assets would lead to major losses for freely managed wealth of investors in advanced economies in current economics.[158]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ "Energy Transition Investment Hit $500 Billion in 2020 – For First Time". BloombergNEF. (Bloomberg New Energy Finance). 19 January 2021. Archived from the original on 19 January 2021.
  2. ^ Catsaros, Oktavia (26 January 2023). "Global Low-Carbon Energy Technology Investment Surges Past $1 Trillion for the First Time". Figure 1: Bloomberg NEF (New Energy Finance). Archived from the original on 22 May 2023. Defying supply chain disruptions and macroeconomic headwinds, 2022 energy transition investment jumped 31% to draw level with fossil fuels{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  3. ^ "Global Clean Energy Investment Jumps 17%, Hits $1.8 Trillion in 2023, According to BloombergNEF Report". BNEF.com. Bloomberg NEF. 30 January 2024. Archived from the original on 28 June 2024. Start years differ by sector but all sectors are present from 2020 onwards.
  4. ^ a b c d Fisher, B.S.; et al. (2007). "Issues related to mitigation in the long term context.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Archived from the original on 16 November 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  5. ^ "The global backlash against climate policies has begun". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. Retrieved 11 November 2023.
  6. ^ a b c d e Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). "Introduction: scope of the assessment.". In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 21, 28, 43. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  7. ^ a b Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "Framing issues". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 127. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  8. ^ a b c Toth, F.L.; et al. (2001). "Decision-making Frameworks". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 607–609. Archived from the original on 13 October 2012. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
  9. ^ Page, Edward A. (August 2008). "Distributing the burdens of climate change". Environmental Politics. 17 (4): 556–575. Bibcode:2008EnvPo..17..556P. doi:10.1080/09644010802193419. ISSN 0964-4016. S2CID 53385652.
  10. ^ a b "What is a carbon price and why do we need one?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
  11. ^ "Understanding carbon pricing". Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
  12. ^ "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
  13. ^ Implementing a US carbon tax : challenges and debates. Parry, Ian W. H. (Ian William Holmes), 1965-, Morris, Adele Cecile, 1963-, Williams, Roberton C., 1972-. New York. 2015. ISBN 978-1-138-81415-8. OCLC 891001377.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) CS1 maint: others (link)
  14. ^ "Pros and cons of a carbon tax » Yale Climate Connections". Yale Climate Connections. 20 July 2016. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
  15. ^ Chen, Zi-yue; Nie, Pu-yan (1 December 2016). "Effects of carbon tax on social welfare: A case study of China". Applied Energy. 183: 1607–1615. Bibcode:2016ApEn..183.1607C. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.09.111. ISSN 0306-2619.
  16. ^ Irfan, Umair (17 May 2019). "Fossil fuels are underpriced by a whopping $5.2 trillion". Vox. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
  17. ^ a b c d Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "Policies, Measures, and Instruments". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Archived from the original on 5 March 2016. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  18. ^ a b "Cap and Trade: Key Terms Glossary" (PDF). Climate Change 101. Center for Climate and Energy Solutions. January 2011. Archived from the original (PDF) on 5 October 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  19. ^ "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
  20. ^ a b Goulder, Lawrence; Schein, Andrew (August 2013). "Carbon Taxes vs. Cap and Trade: A Critical Review". NBER Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w19338. S2CID 158104668.
  21. ^ Thomas Wiedmann; Manfred Lenzen; Lorenz T. Keyßer; Julia Steinberger (19 June 2020). "Scientists' warning on affluence". Nature Communications. 11 (1): 3107. Bibcode:2020NatCo..11.3107W. doi:10.1038/s41467-020-16941-y. PMC 7305220. PMID 32561753.
  22. ^ "Why GDP is no longer the most effective measure of economic success". www.worldfinance.com. Retrieved 17 September 2020.
  23. ^ Kapoor, Amit; Debroy, Bibek (4 October 2019). "GDP Is Not a Measure of Human Well-Being". Harvard Business Review. Retrieved 20 September 2020.
  24. ^ Hickel, Jason; Hallegatte, Stéphane (2021). "Can we live within environmental limits and still reduce poverty? Degrowth or decoupling?". Development Policy Review. 40. doi:10.1111/dpr.12584. ISSN 1467-7679. S2CID 239636388.
  25. ^ Landler, Mark; Sengupta, Somini (21 January 2020). "Trump and the Teenager: A Climate Showdown at Davos". The New York Times. Retrieved 20 September 2020.
  26. ^ "Skills for Green Jobs: A Global View" (PDF). Retrieved 8 November 2021.
  27. ^ van der Ree, Kees (1 June 2019). "Promoting Green Jobs: Decent Work in the Transition to Low-Carbon, Green Economies". International Development Policy | Revue internationale de politique de développement (11): 248–271. doi:10.4000/poldev.3107. ISSN 1663-9375. S2CID 197784487.
  28. ^ Hickel, Jason; Kallis, Giorgos; Jackson, Tim; O'Neill, Daniel W.; Schor, Juliet B.; Steinberger, Julia K.; et al. (12 December 2022). "Degrowth can work — here's how science can help". Nature. 612 (7940): 400–403. Bibcode:2022Natur.612..400H. doi:10.1038/d41586-022-04412-x. PMID 36510013. S2CID 254614532. Researchers in ecological economics call for a different approach — degrowth. Wealthy economies should abandon growth of gross domestic product (GDP) as a goal, scale down destructive and unnecessary forms of production to reduce energy and material use, and focus economic activity around securing human needs and well-being.
  29. ^ Foster, John Bellamy (1 July 2023). "Planned Degrowth: Ecosocialism and Sustainable Human Development". Monthly Review. Retrieved 24 August 2023. Degrowth, in this sense, is not aimed at austerity, but at finding a "prosperous way down" from our current extractivist, wasteful, ecologically unsustainable, maldeveloped, exploitative, and unequal, class-hierarchical world. Continued growth would occur in some areas of the economy, made possible by reductions elsewhere. Spending on fossil fuels, armaments, private jets, sport utility vehicles, second homes, and advertising would need to be cut in order to provide room for growth in such areas as regenerative agriculture, food production, decent housing, clean energy, accessible health care, universal education, community welfare, public transportation, digital connectivity, and other areas related to green production and social needs.
  30. ^ Borowy, Iris; Aillon, Jean-Louis (1 August 2017). "Sustainable health and degrowth: Health, health care and society beyond the growth paradigm". Social Theory & Health. 15 (3): 346–368. doi:10.1057/s41285-017-0032-7. ISSN 1477-822X. S2CID 152144759.
  31. ^ Aillon, J.; Cardito, M. (2020). "Health and Degrowth in times of Pandemic".
  32. ^ Missoni, Eduardo (1 July 2015). "Degrowth and health: local action should be linked to global policies and governance for health". Sustainability Science. 10 (3): 439–450. Bibcode:2015SuSc...10..439M. doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0300-1. ISSN 1862-4057. S2CID 55806403. Volume and increase of spending in the health sector contribute to economic growth, but do not consistently relate with better health. Instead, unsatisfactory health trends, health systems' inefficiencies, and high costs are linked to the globalization of a growth society dominated by neoliberal economic ideas and policies of privatization, deregulation, and liberalization. A degrowth approach, understood as frame that connects diverse ideas, concepts, and proposals alternative to growth as a societal objective, can contribute to better health and a more efficient use of health systems.
  33. ^ Büchs, Milena; Koch, Max (1 January 2019). "Challenges for the degrowth transition: The debate about wellbeing". Futures. 105: 155–165. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2018.09.002. ISSN 0016-3287. S2CID 149731503. The first part reviews the arguments that degrowth proponents have put forward on the ways in which degrowth can maintain or even improve wellbeing. It also outlines why the basic needs approach is most suitable for conceptualising wellbeing in a degrowth context. The second part considers additional challenges to maintaining or even improving current levels of wellbeing under degrowth
  34. ^ Kostakis, Vasilis; Latoufis, Kostas; Liarokapis, Minas; Bauwens, Michel (1 October 2018). "The convergence of digital commons with local manufacturing from a degrowth perspective: Two illustrative cases". Journal of Cleaner Production. 197: 1684–1693. Bibcode:2018JCPro.197.1684K. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.09.077. ISSN 0959-6526. S2CID 43975556. A large part of the activity taking place under the CBPP umbrella presents a lot of similarities with the degrowth concept of unpaid work and decommodification (Nierling, 2012). The majority of "peers" engaged in commons-oriented projects are motivated by passion, communication, learning and enrichment (Benkler, 2006, 2011). Kostakis et al. (2015, 2016) have only theoretically and conceptually explored the contours of an emerging productive model that builds on the convergence of the digital commons of knowledge, software and design with local manufacturing technologies. They tentatively call it "design global, manufacture local"
  35. ^ Scarrow, Ryan (April 2018). "Work and degrowth". Nature Sustainability. 1 (4): 159. Bibcode:2018NatSu...1..159S. doi:10.1038/s41893-018-0057-5. ISSN 2398-9629. S2CID 149576398.
  36. ^ Haberl, Helmut; Wiedenhofer, Dominik; Virág, Doris; Kalt, Gerald; Plank, Barbara; Brockway, Paul; Fishman, Tomer; Hausknost, Daniel; Krausmann, Fridolin; Leon-Gruchalski, Bartholomäus; Mayer, Andreas; Pichler, Melanie; Schaffartzik, Anke; Sousa, Tânia; Streeck, Jan; Creutzig, Felix (10 June 2020). "A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and GHG emissions, part II: synthesizing the insights". Environmental Research Letters. 15 (6): 065003. Bibcode:2020ERL....15f5003H. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab842a. ISSN 1748-9326. S2CID 216453887.
  37. ^ Hickel, Jason (3 October 2021). "What does degrowth mean? A few points of clarification". Globalizations. 18 (7): 1105–1111. Bibcode:2021Glob...18.1105H. doi:10.1080/14747731.2020.1812222. ISSN 1474-7731. S2CID 221800076.
  38. ^ Millward-Hopkins, Joel; Steinberger, Julia K.; Rao, Narasimha D.; Oswald, Yannick (1 November 2020). "Providing decent living with minimum energy: A global scenario". Global Environmental Change. 65: 102168. Bibcode:2020GEC....6502168M. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2020.102168. ISSN 0959-3780. S2CID 224977493.
  39. ^ Browning, Noah; Kelly, Stephanie (8 March 2022). "Analysis: Ukraine crisis could boost ballooning fossil fuel subsidies". Reuters. Retrieved 2 April 2022.
  40. ^ "Energy subsidies – Topics". IEA. Archived from the original on 26 January 2021. Retrieved 27 October 2020.
  41. ^ "Data – Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development". oecd.org. Archived from the original on 10 November 2020. Retrieved 27 October 2020.
  42. ^ Irfan, Umair (17 May 2019). "Fossil fuels are underpriced by a whopping $5.2 trillion". Vox. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
  43. ^ Laville, Sandra (24 October 2019). "Fossil fuel big five 'spent €251m lobbying EU' since 2010". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
  44. ^ "Breaking up with fossil fuels". UNDP. Archived from the original on 3 June 2023. Retrieved 24 November 2022.
  45. ^ Gencsu, Ipek; Walls, Ginette; Picciariello, Angela; Alasia, Ibifuro Joy (2 November 2022). "Nigeria's energy transition: reforming fossil fuel subsidies and other financing opportunities". ODI: Think change. Retrieved 24 November 2022.
  46. ^ "How Reforming Fossil Fuel Subsidies Can Go Wrong: A lesson from Ecuador". IISD. Retrieved 11 November 2019.
  47. ^ Carrington, Damian (6 October 2021). "Fossil fuel industry gets subsidies of $11m a minute, IMF finds". The Guardian. Archived from the original on 6 October 2021. Retrieved 11 December 2021.
  48. ^ "| Fossil Fuel Subsidies". IMF. Archived from the original on 31 October 2020. Retrieved 27 October 2020.
  49. ^ Barker; et al. (2001). "9.2.1.2 Reducing Subsidies in the Energy Sector". Climate Change 2001: IPCC Third Assessment Report Working Group III: Mitigation. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. p. 568. Archived from the original on 5 August 2009. Retrieved 1 September 2010.
  50. ^ "Fossil Fuel to Clean Energy Subsidy Swaps: How to pay for an energy revolution". IISD. 7 June 2019. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
  51. ^ "Fossil Fuel Subsidies". IMF. Retrieved 2 January 2024. Raising fuel prices to their fully efficient levels reduces projected global fossil fuel CO2 emissions 43 percent below baseline levels in 2030—or 34 percent below 2019 emissions. This reduction is in line with the 25-50 percent reduction in global greenhouse gas emissions below 2019 levels needed by 2030 to be on track with containing global warming to the Paris goal of 1.5-2C.
  52. ^ "Paris Agreement, FCCC/CP/2015/L.9/Rev.1" (PDF). UNFCCC secretariat. Archived (PDF) from the original on 12 December 2015. Retrieved 12 December 2015.
  53. ^ "Reference: C.N.464.2017.TREATIES-XXVII.7.d (Depositary Notification)" (PDF). United Nations. 8 August 2017. Archived (PDF) from the original on 15 August 2017. Retrieved 14 August 2017.
  54. ^ "US makes official return to Paris climate pact". Associated Press. 19 February 2021. Archived from the original on 19 February 2021. Retrieved 19 February 2021 – via The Guardian.
  55. ^ UNFCCC. "The Paris Agreement". unfccc.int. Archived from the original on 19 March 2021. Retrieved 18 September 2021.
  56. ^ Schleussner, Carl-Friedrich. "The Paris Agreement – the 1.5 °C Temperature Goal". Climate Analytics. Retrieved 29 January 2022.
  57. ^ European Commission,2017
  58. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "11.7.2 Carbon leakage.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective - Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Archived from the original on 3 May 2010. Retrieved 5 April 2010.
  59. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007), "11.7.1 The nature and importance of spillover. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website, archived from the original on 11 May 2010, retrieved 5 April 2010
  60. ^ "The "Kaya Identity" | METEO 469: From Meteorology to Mitigation: Understanding Global Warming". www.e-education.psu.edu. Retrieved 29 November 2020.
  61. ^ "Energy Transition Investment Now On Par with Fossil Fuel". Bloomberg NEF (New Energy Finance). 10 February 2023. Archived from the original on 27 March 2023.
  62. ^ "World Energy Investment 2023 / Overview and key findings". International Energy Agency (IEA). 25 May 2023. Archived from the original on 31 May 2023. Global energy investment in clean energy and in fossil fuels, 2015-2023 (chart) — From pages 8 and 12 of World Energy Investment 2023 (archive).
  63. ^ Grubb 2003, p. 144
  64. ^ Staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank (2010). World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change. 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433, USA: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-0-8213-7987-5. ISBN 978-0-8213-7987-5. Retrieved 6 April 2010.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  65. ^ Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations Secretariat (2009). "Overview" (PDF). World Economic and Social Survey 2009: Promoting Development, Saving the Planet. New York, USA: Printed by the United Nations, Publishing Section. ISBN 978-92-1-109159-5. Retrieved 2 July 2011.
  66. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s Jessica Brown and Michael Jacobs 2011. Leveraging private investment: the role of public sector climate finance Archived 10 August 2011 at the Wayback Machine. London: Overseas Development Institute
  67. ^ Brown, J. & M. Jacobs (April 2011). "ODI Background Notes: Leveraging private investment: the role of public sector climate finance" (PDF). Odi Background Note. 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD, UK: Overseas Development Institute (ODI). ISSN 1756-7610. Retrieved 2 July 2011.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  68. ^ a b Bank, European Investment (12 January 2022). EIB Investment Report 2021/2022: Recovery as a springboard for change. European Investment Bank. ISBN 978-92-861-5155-2.
  69. ^ "2021-2022 EIB Climate Survey, part 3 of 3: The economic and social impact of the green transition". EIB.org. Retrieved 4 April 2022.
  70. ^ a b Bank, European Investment (18 May 2022). Business resilience in the pandemic and beyond: Adaptation, innovation, financing and climate action from Eastern Europe to Central Asia. European Investment Bank. ISBN 978-92-861-5086-9.
  71. ^ a b "Pathways to Sustainable Energy" (PDF).
  72. ^ State of Finance for Nature (PDF). 3 United Nations Environment Programme. 2023. Retrieved 29 May 2024.
  73. ^ Harvey, Fiona; Rankin, Jennifer (9 March 2020). "What is the European Green Deal and will it really cost €1tn?". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
  74. ^ Holger, Dieter (15 November 2019). "European Investment Bank Will End Fossil Fuel Financing". Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
  75. ^ "European Investment Bank to phase out fossil fuel financing". the Guardian. 15 November 2019. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
  76. ^ "EU/China/US climate survey shows public optimism about reversing climate change". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
  77. ^ "Climate action". EIB.org. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
  78. ^ Bank, European Investment (17 August 2023). Clean oceans and the blue economy Overview 2023. European Investment Bank. ISBN 978-92-861-5518-5.
  79. ^ "EU, WBIF extend €2.5 million grant to wastewater project in Kosovo". www.ebrd.com. Retrieved 28 August 2023.
  80. ^ "EU invests €70 million in largest wastewater treatment plant in North Macedonia". WBIF.org.
  81. ^ Bank, European Investment (27 February 2024). "Energy Overview 2024". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  82. ^ Bank, European Investment (27 February 2024). "Energy Overview 2024". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  83. ^ a b "EIB Investment Report 2020-2021". EIB.org. Retrieved 15 November 2021.
  84. ^ IANS (10 August 2021). "45% of EU firms report investments to address climate change: Survey". Business Standard India. Retrieved 15 November 2021.
  85. ^ "New EIB study: How do EU and US firms perceive and invest in climate change?". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 15 November 2021.
  86. ^ "Cohesion support after the pandemic". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 15 November 2021.
  87. ^ "THE STATE OF LOCAL INFRASTRUCTURE INVESTMENT IN EUROPE: EIB Municipality Survey 2020" (PDF). European Investment Bank. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2 August 2021.
  88. ^ a b c d Bank, European Investment (2 August 2021). The state of local infrastructure investment in Europe: EIB Municipalities Survey 2020. European Investment Bank. ISBN 978-92-861-4954-2.
  89. ^ "The territorial impact of COVID-19: Managing the crisis across levels of government". OECD. Retrieved 30 May 2022.
  90. ^ a b c d e f g h Markandya, A.; et al. (2001). "Costing Methodologies. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 474–476. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
  91. ^ "Chapter 2: Emissions trends and drivers" (PDF). Ipcc_Ar6_Wgiii. 2022. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 April 2022. Retrieved 10 April 2022.
  92. ^ "No Regrets: Circles of Climate Change Adaptation – Principles and Practices for Responding to Climate Change". Retrieved 20 May 2021.
  93. ^ Philander, S. George (2012). Encyclopedia of Global Warming & Climate Change. SAGE Publications, Inc. p. 1720. doi:10.4135/9781452218564. ISBN 978-1-4129-9261-9.
  94. ^ "AR6 wg3 ts" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 April 2022. Retrieved 4 April 2022.
  95. ^ a b IPCC (2007c). "Annex. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 819. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  96. ^ "Coal exit benefits outweigh its costs — PIK Research Portal". www.pik-potsdam.de. Archived from the original on 24 March 2020. Retrieved 24 March 2020.
  97. ^ "The Sixth Carbon Budget Surface Transport" (PDF). UKCCC. there is zero net cost to the economy of switching from cars to walking and cycling
  98. ^ a b John Weyant. (2017) Some Contributions of Integrated Assessment Models of Global Climate Change. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 11:1, 115-137
  99. ^ Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996b). Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: Prof. Joseph Stiglitz's web page at Columbia University. pp. 125–144. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. Retrieved 11 February 2010.
  100. ^ Nordhaus, William (2014). "Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches". Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. 1: 273–312. doi:10.1086/676035. S2CID 155012348.
  101. ^ IPCC (2001a). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
  102. ^ Nordhaus, W. (2008) A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies Archived 25 May 2017 at the Wayback Machine Yale University Press pp. 10-11
  103. ^ Ackerman, F. (2007) Debating Climate Economics: The Stern Review vs. Its Critics Archived 3 October 2016 at the Wayback Machine Global Development and Environment Institute
  104. ^ Anthoff, D., R.S.J.Tol, and G.W.Yohe (2009), 'Discounting for Climate Change', Economics -- the Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 3, (2009-24), pp. 1-24.
  105. ^ U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) December 2010, Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses: Discounting Future Benefits and Costs
  106. ^ "The Use of Discount Rates" (PDF). European Commission - European Commission. Retrieved 24 August 2020.
  107. ^ Frederick, Shane; Loewenstein, George; O'Donoghue, Ted (June 2002). "Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review". Journal of Economic Literature. 40 (2): 351–401. doi:10.1257/002205102320161311. ISSN 0022-0515.
  108. ^ a b c Heal, G. M. (1997). Discounting and climate change. Columbia Business School, Columbia University. OCLC 760924527.
  109. ^ a b c De Guzman, Franklin Liang, Zhihong Lin, Tun Zhuang, Juzhong. Theory and practice in the choice of social discount rate for cost-benefit analysis : a survey (PDF). Asian Development Bank. pp. 17–18. OCLC 836563664.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  110. ^ United States. Office of Management and Budget. (17 September 2003). Regulatory analysis. Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget. OCLC 54768341.
  111. ^ "Budget Assumptions" (PDF). whitehouse.gov. 5 November 2019. Retrieved 24 August 2020 – via National Archives.
  112. ^ Cropper, Maureen L.; Freeman, Mark C.; Groom, Ben; Pizer, William A. (1 May 2014). "Declining Discount Rates". American Economic Review. 104 (5): 538–543. doi:10.1257/aer.104.5.538. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 3065184.
  113. ^ Farber, David A. (7 April 2014). "The Case for Declining Discount Rates | The Regulatory Review". www.theregreview.org. Retrieved 24 August 2020.
  114. ^ Groom, Ben; Hepburn, Cameron; Koundouri, Phoebe; Pearce, David (1 December 2005). "Declining Discount Rates: The Long and the Short of it". Environmental and Resource Economics. 32 (4): 445–493. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.334.8633. doi:10.1007/s10640-005-4681-y. ISSN 1573-1502. S2CID 17750962.
  115. ^ Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996a). Decision-making frameworks for addressing climate change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. p. 57. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  116. ^ Munasinghe, M.; et al. (1996). Applicability of Techniques of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Climate Change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  117. ^ "WG III contribution to the Sixth Assessment Report" (PDF). Ipcc_Ar6_Wgiii. 2022. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 April 2022. Retrieved 10 April 2022.
  118. ^ a b Arrow, K. J.; et al., "2.3.2 Decision analysis and climate change. In (book chapter) 2. Decision-Making Frameworks for Addressing Climate Change", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 62–63 (p.65-66 of PDF)
  119. ^ Goldemberg, J.; et al., "1.3.1.2 Risk aversion. In (book chapter) 1. Introduction: Scope of the Assessment", IPCC SAR WG3 1996, pp. 24–25 (p.30-31 of PDF)
  120. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 8 June 2011. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  121. ^ IPCC, 2007: Technical Summary - Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Archived 2009-12-11 at the Wayback Machine [B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, L.A. Meyer (eds)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, United States., XXX pp.
  122. ^ a b Stern, N. (2006). Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change: Part III: The Economics of Stabilisation. HM Treasury, London: http://hm-treasury.gov.uk/sternreview_index.htm
  123. ^ Sampedro, Jon; Smith, Steven J.; Arto, Iñaki; González-Eguino, Mikel; Markandya, Anil; Mulvaney, Kathleen M.; Pizarro-Irizar, Cristina; Van Dingenen, Rita (2020). "Health co-benefits and mitigation costs as per the Paris Agreement under different technological pathways for energy supply". Environment International. 136: 105513. Bibcode:2020EnInt.13605513S. doi:10.1016/j.envint.2020.105513. hdl:10810/44202. PMID 32006762. S2CID 211004787.
  124. ^ a b "Can cost benefit analysis grasp the climate change nettle? And can we..." Oxford Martin School. Retrieved 11 November 2019.
  125. ^ Kotz, Mazimilian.; Levermann, Anders; Wenz, Leonie (17 April 2024). "The economic commitment of climate change". Nature. 628 (8008): 551–557. Bibcode:2024Natur.628..551K. doi:10.1038/s41586-024-07219-0. PMC 11023931. PMID 38632481.
  126. ^ "Below 1.5°C: a breakthrough roadmap to solve the climate crisis". One Earth. Retrieved 21 November 2022.
  127. ^ Teske, Sven, ed. (2 August 2019). Achieving the Paris Climate Agreement Goals: Global and Regional 100% Renewable Energy Scenarios with Non-energy GHG Pathways for +1.5°C and +2°C. Springer Science+Business Media. doi:10.1007/978-3-030-05843-2. ISBN 978-3030058425. S2CID 198078901 – via www.springer.com.
  128. ^ "The crucial intersection between gender and climate". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 29 December 2023.
  129. ^ Nations, United. "Finance & Justice". United Nations. Retrieved 29 December 2023.
  130. ^ IPCC (2022). Shukla, P.R.; Skea, J.; Slade, R.; Al Khourdajie, A.; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. p. 300.: The global benefits of pathways limiting warming to 2°C (>67%) outweigh global mitigation costs over the 21st century, if aggregated economic impacts of climate change are at the moderate to high end of the assessed range, and a weight consistent with economic theory is given to economic impacts over the long term. This holds true even without accounting for benefits in other sustainable development dimensions or nonmarket damages from climate change (medium confidence).
  131. ^ IPCC (2022) Chapter 3: Mitigation pathways compatible with long-term goals in Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, United States
  132. ^ Evans, Stuart; Mehling, Michael A.; Ritz, Robert A.; Sammon, Paul (16 March 2021). "Border carbon adjustments and industrial competitiveness in a European Green Deal". Climate Policy. 21 (3): 307–317. doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1856637. ISSN 1469-3062.
  133. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 8 June 2011. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  134. ^ a b IPCC (2007b). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 5 October 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
  135. ^ "Emissions Gap Report 2020 / Executive Summary" (PDF). UNEP.org. Fig. ES.8: United Nations Environment Programme. 2021. p. XV. Archived (PDF) from the original on 31 July 2021.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  136. ^ Climate Equality: a Climate for the 99% (PDF). Oxfam International. November 2023. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 November 2023. Fig. ES.2, Fig. ES.3, Box 1.2.
  137. ^ Gupta, S.; et al. (2007), "Policies, Instruments and Co-operative Arrangements.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A., archived from the original on 5 October 2018, retrieved 20 May 2009
  138. ^ a b Barker, T.; et al. (2001), "Sectoral Costs and Ancillary Benefits of Mitigation.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, archived from the original on 5 October 2018, retrieved 10 January 2010
  139. ^ a b c Banuri, T.; et al. (1996). Equity and Social Considerations. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J. P. Bruce et al. eds.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521568548. PDF version: IPCC website.
  140. ^ a b Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). Introduction: scope of the assessment. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J. P. Bruce et al. eds.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521568548. Web version: IPCC website.
  141. ^ Longo, Albert; Hoyos, David; Markandya, Anil (January 2011). "Willingness to Pay for Ancillary Benefits of Climate Change Mitigation". ResearchGate.
  142. ^ a b c Timperley, Jocelyn. "Who is really to blame for climate change?". www.bbc.com. Retrieved 8 June 2022.
  143. ^ Tallarita, Roberto (9 August 2021). "The Limits of Portfolio Primacy". SSRN 3912977.
  144. ^ "Paying the Cost of Climate Change". Brookings. Retrieved 7 December 2023.
  145. ^ Mintz-Woo, Kian; Leroux, Justin (November 2021). "What do climate change winners owe, and to whom?". Economics & Philosophy. 37 (3): 462–483. doi:10.1017/S0266267120000449. hdl:10468/11123. ISSN 0266-2671.
  146. ^ Rosenbloom, Daniel; Markard, Jochen; Geels, Frank W.; Fuenfschilling, Lea (21 April 2020). "Why carbon pricing is not sufficient to mitigate climate change—and how "sustainability transition policy" can help". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 117 (16): 8664–8668. Bibcode:2020PNAS..117.8664R. doi:10.1073/pnas.2004093117. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 7183151. PMID 32269079.
  147. ^ Bartolomeo, Giovanni Di; Fard, Behnaz Minooei; Semmler, Willi (June 2023). "Greenhouse gases mitigation: global externalities and short-termism" (PDF). Environment and Development Economics. 28 (3): 230–241. doi:10.1017/S1355770X22000249. ISSN 1355-770X.
  148. ^ Meredith, Sam (7 February 2022). "World's biggest companies accused of exaggerating their climate actions". CNBC. Retrieved 8 June 2022.
  149. ^ Papaoikonomou, Eleni; Ginieis, Matías; Alarcón, Amado Alarcón (15 November 2023). "The Problematics of Being an Ethical Consumer in the Marketplace: Unpacking the Concept of Ethical Consumer Literacy". Journal of Public Policy & Marketing. 43 (2): 133–150. doi:10.1177/07439156231202746. ISSN 0743-9156. Instead of placing the responsibility on individual consumers, governments should increase ethical consumer literacy.
  150. ^ "AR6 Synthesis Report: Climate Change 2023 — IPCC". Retrieved 18 April 2023.
  151. ^ Hoang, Nguyen Tien; Kanemoto, Keiichiro (June 2021). "Mapping the deforestation footprint of nations reveals growing threat to tropical forests". Nature Ecology & Evolution. 5 (6): 845–853. Bibcode:2021NatEE...5..845H. doi:10.1038/s41559-021-01417-z. ISSN 2397-334X.
  152. ^ "Supermarket food could soon carry eco-labels, says study". 9 August 2022. Retrieved 7 December 2023.
  153. ^ Clark, Michael; Springmann, Marco; Rayner, Mike; Scarborough, Peter; Hill, Jason; Tilman, David; Macdiarmid, Jennie I.; Fanzo, Jessica; Bandy, Lauren; Harrington, Richard A. (16 August 2022). "Estimating the environmental impacts of 57,000 food products". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 119 (33): e2120584119. Bibcode:2022PNAS..11920584C. doi:10.1073/pnas.2120584119. hdl:2164/20863. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 9388151. PMID 35939701.
  154. ^ Kolcava, Dennis; Smith, E. Keith; Bernauer, Thomas (January 2023). "Cross-national public acceptance of sustainable global supply chain policy instruments". Nature Sustainability. 6 (1): 69–80. doi:10.1038/s41893-022-00984-8. ISSN 2398-9629.
  155. ^ "Skills for Green Jobs: A Global View" (PDF). Retrieved 8 November 2021.
  156. ^ van der Ree, Kees (1 June 2019). "Promoting Green Jobs: Decent Work in the Transition to Low-Carbon, Green Economies". International Development Policy | Revue internationale de politique de développement (11): 248–271. doi:10.4000/poldev.3107. ISSN 1663-9375. S2CID 197784487.
  157. ^ Trout, Kelly; Muttitt, Greg; Lafleur, Dimitri; Van de Graaf, Thijs; Mendelevitch, Roman; Mei, Lan; Meinshausen, Malte (17 May 2022). "Existing fossil fuel extraction would warm the world beyond 1.5 °C". Environmental Research Letters. 17 (6): 064010. Bibcode:2022ERL....17f4010T. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ac6228. hdl:1854/LU-8753303. ISSN 1748-9326. S2CID 248853320.
  158. ^ Semieniuk, Gregor; Holden, Philip B.; Mercure, Jean-Francois; Salas, Pablo; Pollitt, Hector; Jobson, Katharine; Vercoulen, Pim; Chewpreecha, Unnada; Edwards, Neil R.; Viñuales, Jorge E. (June 2022). "Stranded fossil-fuel assets translate to major losses for investors in advanced economies". Nature Climate Change. 12 (6): 532–538. Bibcode:2022NatCC..12..532S. doi:10.1038/s41558-022-01356-y. hdl:11385/223918. ISSN 1758-6798. S2CID 249069181.

Sources

[edit]
[edit]
  • IPCC Working Group III (WG III). This body assesses options for mitigating climate change through limiting or preventing greenhouse gas emissions and enhancing activities that remove them from the atmosphere.

Licensed under CC BY-SA 3.0 | Source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economics_of_climate_change_mitigation
7 views |
Download as ZWI file
Encyclosphere.org EncycloReader is supported by the EncyclosphereKSF